NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES
NEW KEYNESIAN VERSUS OLD KEYNESIAN GOVERNMENT SPENDING MULTIPLIERS
John F. Cogan
Tobias Cwik
John B. Taylor
Volker Wieland
Working Paper 14782
http://www.nber.org/papers/w14782
NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH
1050 Massachusetts Avenue
Cambridge, MA 02138
March 2009
¸˛Helpful comments by Gunter Coenen, Alistair Dieppe, Frank Smets, and Rafael Wouters are gratefully
acknowledged. The views expressed herein are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect
the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research.
NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been peer-
reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies official
NBER publications.
© 2009 by John F. Cogan, Tobias Cwik, John B. Taylor, and Volker Wieland. All rights reserved.
Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided
that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source.
New Keynesian versus Old Keynesian Government Spending Multipliers
John F. Cogan, Tobias Cwik, John B. Taylor, and Volker Wieland
NBER Working Paper No. 14782
March 2009
JEL No. C52,E62
ABSTRACT
Renewed interest in fiscal policy has increased the use of quantitative models to evaluate policy. Because
of modelling uncertainty, it is essential that policy evaluations be robust to alternative assumptions.
We find that models currently being used in practice to evaluate fiscal policy stimulus proposals are
not robust. Government spending multipliers in an alternative empirically-estimated and widely-cited
new Keynesian model are much smaller than in these old Keynesian models; the estimated stimulus
is extremely small just when needed most, and GDP and employment effects are only one-sixth as
large, with private sector employment impacts likely to be even smaller.
John F. Cogan
Hoover Institution
Stanford University
Stanford, CA 94305
Tobias Cwik
Goethe-Universität Frankfurt am Main
House of Finance, PF H 31
D-60323 Frankfurt/Main
John B. Taylor
Herbert Hoover Memorial Building
Stanford University
Stanford, CA 94305-6010
and NBER
Volker Wieland
Goethe-Universität Frankfurt am Main
House of Finance, PF H 31
D-60323 Frankfurt/Main
2
In a recent paper
1
Christina Romer, Chair of the President’s Council of Economic
Advisers, and Jared Bernstein, Chief Economist of the Office of the Vice-President, provided
numerical estimates of the impact of an increase in government spending on GDP and
employment in the United States. Such estimates are a crucial input for the policy making
process. They help determine the appropriate size and timing of countercyclical fiscal policy
packages and they help inform members of the Congress and their constituents about whether
a vote for a policy is appropriate. For packages approaching $1 trillion including interest, as
in 2009, the stakes are enormous. The estimated economic impacts matter.
The Romer-Bernstein estimates are based on two particular quantitative
macroeconomic models – one from the staff of the Federal Reserve Board and the other from
an unnamed private forecasting firm. By averaging the impacts generated by these two
models, they estimate that an increase in government purchases of 1 percent of GDP would
induce an increase in real GDP of 1.6 percent compared to what it otherwise would be. Their
results are shown in Figure 1. Also shown in Figure 1 are the estimated effects of exactly the
same policy change—a permanent increase in government purchases—as reported in another
study published a number of years ago by one of us.
2
It is clear from Figure 1 that the results are vastly different between the different
models. Perhaps the most important difference is that in one case higher government spending
keeps on adding to GDP “as far as the eye can see,” while in the other case the effect on GDP
diminishes as non-government components are crowded out by government spending.
1
See Romer and Bernstein (2009), Appendix 1, page 12. This paper was written during the transition period in
early January before Christina Romer was sworn in as Chair of the Council of Economic Advisers.
2
See Taylor (1993), Figure 5-8A, page 166. This is a rational expectations model with staggered wage and
price setting and thus could be described as “new Keynesian” as defined below.
3
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1.0
1.2
1.4
1.6
2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014
percent change
Romer-Bernstein (2009)
Taylor (1993)
Figure 1. Estimated Impact on GDP of a Permanent Increase in
Government Purchases of 1 percent of GDP
Macroeconomists remain quite uncertain about the quantitative effects of fiscal
policy. This uncertainty derives not only from the usual errors in empirical estimation but also
from different views on the proper theoretical framework and econometric methodology.
Therefore, robustness is a crucial criterion in policy evaluation. Robustness requires
evaluating policies using other empirically-estimated and tested macroeconomic models.
From this perspective Figure 1 is a concern because it shows that the Romer-Bernstein
estimates apparently fail a simple robustness test, being far different from existing published
results of another model. For these reasons an examination of the Romer-Bernstein results is
in order.
4
I. The Need for an Alternative Assessment
We think it is best to start by conducting a fresh set of simulations with a
macroeconomic model other than one of those used in Figure 1. We focus on the Smets-
Wouters model of the U.S. economy.
3
The Smets-Wouters model is representative of current
thinking in macroeconomics. It was recently published in the American Economic Review and
is one of the best known of the empirically-estimated “new Keynesian” models. It is very
similar to, and “largely based on” according to Smets and Wouters, another well-known
empirically-estimated new Keynesian model developed by Christiano, Eichenbaum and Evans
(2005). The Smets-Wouters model was highlighted by Michael Woodford (2009) as one of
the leading models in his review of the current consensus in macroeconomics.
4
The term “new Keynesian” is used to indicate that the models have forward looking,
or rational, expectations by individuals and firms, and some form of price rigidity, usually
staggered price or wage setting. The term also is used to contrast these models with “old
Keynesian” models without rational expectations of the kind used by Romer and Bernstein.
5
New Keynesian models rather than old Keynesian models are the ones commonly taught in
graduate schools because they capture how people’s expectations and microeconomic
behavior change over time in response to policy interventions and because they are
empirically est
imated and fit the data. They are therefore viewed as better for policy
ev
aluation. In assessing the effect of government actions on the economy, it is important to
3
See Smets and Wouters (2007) for a complete review of their model. It determines 14 endogenous variables:
output, consumption, investment, the price of capital, the capital stock, capital services, the capital utilization
rate, labor supply, the interest rate, the inflation rate, the rental rate on capital, the wage rate, the marginal
product of labor, and the marginal rate of substitution between work and consumption. The 14 equations include
forward looking consumption, investment, price and wage setting as well as several identities.
4
See Woodford (2009), which also contains a useful survey of the whole “new Keynesian” literature.
5
There is a rational expectations version of the FRB/US model. We simulated a permanent increase in
government purchases in this version and found that the multipliers declined sharply over time unlike those
reported by Romer and Bernstein (2009) but similar to the Taylor (1993) rational expectations model as shown
in Figure1. We infer that the FRB/US model and the private sector model used by Romer and Bernstien are not
new Keynesian models with rational expectations. Also, as explained below, new Keynesian models would not
allow an assumption of a constant zero interest rate forever.
5
take into account how households and firms adjust their spending decisions as their
expectations of future government policy changes.
We first show that the assumptions made by Romer and Bernstein about monetary
policy—essentially an interest rate peg for the Federal Reserve—are highly questionable
according to new Keynesian models. We therefore modify that assumption and look at the
impacts of a permanent increase in government purchases of goods and services in the
alternative model. According to the alternative model the impacts are much smaller than
those reported by Romer and Bernstein.
We then consider more realistic scenarios. We look at the impact when government
spending follows the fiscal policy legislation enacted in February 2008 and we look at a
scenario in which monetary policy is more responsive. For these scenarios the impact with the
alternative model is even smaller.
II. The Problem with an Interest Rate Peg
Romer and Bernstein assume that the Federal Reserve pegs the interest rate—the
federal funds rate—at the current level of zero for as long as their simulations run. Given their
assumption that the spending increase is permanent, this means forever. In fact, such a pure
interest rate peg is prohibited in new Keynesian models with forward-looking households and
firms because it produces calamitous economic consequences. As Thomas Sargent and Neil
Wallace
6
pointed out more than thirty years ago, a pure interest rate peg will lead to instability
and non-uniqueness in a rational expectations model. Inflation expectations of households and
firms become unanchored and unhinged and the price level may explode in an upward spiral.
A permanent increase in government spending as a share of GDP would eventually
raise the real interest rate. This is the mechanism by which other shares of spending
6
See Sargent and Wallace (1975). Though the Sargent and Wallace model assumes perfectly flexible prices the
same results hold in models with sticky prices.
6
(consumption, investment, and net exports) would be reduced to make room for the increased
government share. With the Fed holding the nominal interest rate constant at the current
value near zero, and thus below inflation, the lower real rate would cause inflation to rise and
accelerate without limit. Thus the combination of a permanent increase in government
spending and the Fed setting the interest rate at zero would lead to hyperinflation.
If the combination of a permanent government spending increase and a zero interest
rate peg were assessed by the Smets-Wouter model or, for that matter, any of the new
Keynesian models, the economy’s projected performance would reflect the aforementioned
consequences. To achieve stability of output and inflation in such a model one must instead
assume that, at some point, the federal funds rate is allowed to move above zero and respond
to the state of the economy rather than be held fixed.
For the simulations presented here we therefore assume that the Federal Reserve only
keeps the federal funds rate constant for a finite period of time after which it moves the
interest rate depending on what is happening to the economy. We begin by assuming that it
keeps the interest rate equal to zero and constant through 2009 and 2010 and then follows a
standard monetary policy rule thereafter. Thus, in 2011, nominal interest rates will change
somewhat and forward-looking households and firms will incorporate this monetary policy
response in their decision making. Keeping interest rates constant for two years still does not
seem very realistic and would likely result in an increase in inflation, but it is certainly more
realistic than pegging the interest rates at zero forever, or even for four years.
III. Government Spending Multipliers: New Keynesian versus Old Keynesian
Table 1 shows the response of real GDP to a permanent increase in government
purchases of 1 percent of GDP in the new Keynesian model and contrasts these with the
average of the two models of Romer and Bernstein. The simulations are done using a new
database of macroeconomic models designed explicitly with the purpose of doing such policy
7
evaluation and robustness studies.
7
The increase in government spending is assumed to start
in the first quarter of calendar 2009. The forward looking models require explicit
assumptions about what household’s and firms expect. Our assumption is that, as of the first
quarter of 2009, people expect the government spending increase to continue permanently (as
in the Romer-Bernstein policy specification), and that the spending increase is initially debt-
financed. The Smets-Wouters model assumes that any increase in debt used to finance the
increased government spending is paid off with interest by raising taxes in the future. We
assume that these taxes are “lump sum” in the sense that they not affect incentives to work,
save or invest. They do, however, lower future after tax earnings and thereby wealth. If we
took such incentive effects into account the increase in government spending would
eventually reduce real GDP. Hence, our assumptions err on the side of overestimating the
size of the impact of government spending on real GDP.
Table 1: Impact of a Permanent Increase in Government Spending by 1 Percent of GDP
(federal funds rate set to zero throughout 2009 and 2010)
Percentage increase in real GDP
2009Q1 2009Q4 2010Q4 2011Q4 2012Q4
Romer/Bernstein 1.05 1.44 1.57 1.57 1.55
Smets/Wouters 1.03 0.89 0.61 0.44 0.40
Observe that the Smets-Wouters model predicts a much smaller boost to GDP than the
estimates reported by Romer and Bernstein. The Smets-Wouters multiplier is smaller
throughout the whole simulation period, and by 2011 is only about one-third the size of the
Romer-Bernstein multiplier. The Smets-Wouters model also shows a rapid reduction in the
size of the impact over time. Overall the Smets-Wouters impacts are very similar in size and
7
The model database is described in Wieland, Cwik, Mueller, Schmidt and Wolters (2009) and used in a model
comparison exercise by Taylor and Wieland (2008)
.
8
timing to those found in the Taylor (1993) model shown in Figure 1. In sum, the Romer-
Bernstein estimates are much more optimistic in their GDP estimates than the alternative
model considered here.
The Smets-Wouters model predicts that the increase in GDP by the end of 2009 is
smaller than the increase in government expenditures itself; that is, the multiplier is less than
one. Thus, the model predicts that government “stimulus” quickly produces a permanent
contraction in private sector investment and/or consumption. Note that the magnitude of the
contraction grows over time. By the end of 2012, for each dollar of “stimulus”, the flow of
goods and services produced by the private sector falls by sixty cents.
IV. Alternative Assumptions about Monetary Policy
Table 2 shows what would happen if the length of time for which the federal funds
rate is anticipated to remain constant is shorter and extends only through the end of 2009. In
other words we now assume that the Fed starts following its feedback rule for policy starting
in 2010 rather than waiting until 2011.
Table 2: Impact of a Permanent Increase in Government Spending By 1 Percent of GDP
(federal funds rate set to zero throughout 2009)
The impacts in Table 2 are uniformly smaller through 2011 than those in Table 1
because interest rates can begin to increase earlier (in 2010 rather than 2011) accelerating the
crowding out process in the new Keynesian model. Note that the differences between the
Smets-Wouters simulations in Table 1 and 2 are not nearly as large as the differences between
Percentage increase in real GDP
2009Q1 2009Q4 2010Q4 2011Q4 2012Q4
Romer/Bernstein 1.05 1.44 1.57 1.57 1.55
Smets/Wouters 0.96 0.67 0.48 0.41 0.40
9
either of these and the Romer-Bernstein impacts. In what follows we will continue with the
assumption that the Fed can start to increase interest rates if necessary in 2010.
V. A More Realistic Path for Government Purchases
Although a permanent increase in government purchases of goods and services is a
good way to understand the properties of a model, it is not a realistic description of the fiscal
policy packages under consideration in the United States and other countries recently nor of
the final $787 billion fiscal stimulus package enacted and signed into law
8
on February 17,
2009. For example, about half of that fiscal stimulus package consists of transfer payments
for unemployment assistance, nutritional aid, and health and welfare payments, and temporary
tax cuts. In addition, the package does not provide for an immediate permanent increase in
government purchases of goods and services. Most of the purchases authorized by the law are
one-time and phased in, with the lion’s share of the purchases completed within four years.
Table 3 shows the U.S. fiscal stimulus package’s impact on the federal deficit and
federal government purchases in billions of dollars. The government purchases column
corresponds to the permanent increase in government purchases simulated and reported in
Tables 1 and 2 except of course that it is not permanent. Observe that $21 billion or just 2.6
percent of the total $787 billion increase in the deficit spending occurs in fiscal year 2009,
which is when the economy is expected to be weakest.
9
Federal purchases then increase in
2010, stay relatively steady for two years, and then begin to decline again in 2012. Since the
stimulus bill is a mixture of increased transfer payments, tax refunds, and higher government
purchases, the path for the deficit is different from the path of the increase in government
purchases.
8
The official name of the legislation is The American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009.
9
The U.S. government’s 2009 fiscal year runs from October 1, 2008 to September 30
th
, 2009.
10
One component of federal government transfers—certain transfers going to state and
local governments—is similar to federal purchases in that the funds are to be used by the
states to purchase goods and services. These intergovernmental transfers, which consist
mainly of funds for education and public safety activities, are shown in the third column of
Table 3. During the first three years, these government transfers exceed federal purchases. It
is difficult to determine how much of the transfers to states and localities will ultimately result
in an increase in spending on goods and services. States and localities might use some or all
of the funds to avoid raising taxes or increasing borrowing. To the extent that they do, the
transfer would not produce a net increase in government purchases of goods and services.
Romer and Bernstein (2009) assume that 60 percent of these transfers go to purchases of
goods and services. In keeping with that assumption, we consider in what follows the impact
on GDP of an increase in government purchases equal to column 2 plus 60 percent of column
3 in Table 3. We assume that the path of purchases is constant for all the quarters within a
fiscal year and that, as assumed Romer and Bernstein (2009), there is a one quarter lag in the
effect of the increase of transfers to states and localities on their purchases of goods and
purchases. We also experimented with other interpolation schemes but the results were not
substantially different and we focus here on the simple constant level assumption.
11
Table 3. Increased Deficit, Federal Government Purchases, and Transfers to State and
Local Governments for Purchases of Goods and Services in the February 2009 Stimulus
Legislation (billions of dollars)
Fiscal Increase Increase Increase
Year in Federal in Transfers to in Federal
Purchases States, Localities Deficit*
2009 21 48 184
2010 47 107 400
2011 46 47 134
2012 36 8 36
2013 25 4 27
1014 27 0 22
2015 11 0 5
2016 -2 0 -8
2017 -3 0 -7
2018 -2 0 -6
Source: Authors’ calculations derived from Congressional Budget Office, “Cost Estimate for
Conference Agreement for H.R.1”, February 13, 2009
*Excludes impact of interest payments on the public debt incurred to finance the stimulus
package.
Figure 2 presents the results of the simulation. The bar graph shows the increased
government purchases as a share of GDP, and the line graph shows the impact of the increase
in purchases on real GDP according to the Smets-Wouters model. The quarters in Figure 2
refer to the calendar year rather than the fiscal year. We show the results through 2013 even
though we simulate the impacts over the full ten years.
12
-.1
.0
.1
.2
.3
.4
.5
.6
.7
.8
2009 2010 2011 2012 2013
Government purchases
Impact on GDP
Percent of GDP
Figure 2. Estimated Output Effects of Government Purchases in the February
2009 Stimulus Legislation. (Government purchases equal federal purchases plus 60
percent of transfers to state and local governments for purchases of goods and
services)
VI. Estimated Impacts
According to the Smets-Wouters model, the impacts of this package on GDP are very
small. But particularly worrisome is that during the first year the estimated stimulus is minor
and then even turns down in the third quarter. Why the very small effect in the first year?
The answer comes in part from the timing of the government expenditures and the
forward-looking perspective of households. The small amount of government spending in the
first year is followed by a larger increase in the second year. Households and firms anticipate
the second year increase during the first year. They also anticipate that ultimately the
expenditures will be financed by higher taxes. The negative impact of the delayed
government spending and the negative wealth effect on private consumption of higher
13
anticipated future taxes combine to reduce the positive impact of the stimulus. As a result, the
first-year GDP impact is initially small and turns down.
In the Smets-Wouters model there is also a strong crowding out of investment. Hence,
both consumption and investment decline as a share of GDP in the first year according to the
Smets-Wouters model. This negative effect is offset, as shown in Figure 1, by the increase in
government spending in the first year, but it causes the multiplier to be below one right from
the start. Figure 3 shows the impact on consumption and investment.
-.4
-.2
.0
.2
.4
.6
.8
2009 2010 2011 2012 2013
Government purchases (G)
Consumption (C)
Investment (I)
C plus I
Percent of GDP
Figure 3. Crowding Out of Consumption and Investment in the
February 2009 Stimulus Legislation (Government purchases are
as in Figure 2)
Note that as the government purchases come back down in 2013, the multiplier turns
negative. The declines in consumption plus investment are greater than the increases in
government spending. Though not shown in Figure 2, the simulations show that the impact on
GDP is negative for many years beyond 2013.
14
Because of the negative effects on consumption and investment, it is possible to get
negative GDP multipliers in the first year with government purchases paths slightly different
from those in Figures 2 and 3. For example, a sharper increase in government spending in the
second year compared to the first leads to more crowding out of consumption and investment
in the first year and the multiplier can turn negative. In fact, our simulations of the first
stimulus bill passed by the House of Representatives in 2009 had this property, but changes
by the conference committee and revised estimates of the path of government purchases by
the Congressional Budget Office removed the negative multiplier.
There is a large literature on whether an increase in government spending reduces
consumption and investment in real business cycle models, and the literature carries over to
some degree to new Keynesian models with sticky prices and wages like the Smets-Wouters
model. See Coenen and Straub (2005) for a discussion and references to many other
contributions. In the standard real business cycle model government spending has a negative
wealth effect. Households consume less. Investment also declines.
A possible criticism of new Keynesian models like the Smets-Wouters model is that
they are not Keynesian enough, because they assume that all households are forward-looking
and optimize their spending decisions. Some have suggested that one should allow for the
possibility that some households follow “rules of thumb” like the original Keynesian
consumption function with a high and constant marginal propensity to consume. Others have
suggested that one should assume that many households are constrained to consume all their
current income. See for example, Gali, Lopez-Salido, Valles (2007). However, Coenen and
Straub (2005), show that it is empirically unlikely that an increase in government spending
crowds in consumption even with such assumptions. There are two reasons: the estimated
share of constrained households is relatively low and the negative wealth effects induced by
government spending shocks are large.
15
Although some might worry that new Keynesian models are faulty because they miss
old Keynesian rule-of-thumb or constrained consumers, we note that the Smets-Wouters
model is estimated and it fits the data well. People might also worry that the small and
negative multipliers depend on assumptions about monetary policy responses and the
particular time profiles of fiscal spending packages. It is for this reason that we have used
actual data on fiscal policy and realistic assumptions about monetary policy.
It is also possible to criticize new Keynesian models such as Smets-Wouters because
they are too Keynesian. In contrast with real business cycle models, the estimated new
Keynesian models assume “sticky prices” by introducing staggered price and wage setting.
But as Chari, Kehoe, and McGrattan (2009) have emphasized the models go further in the
Keynesian direction by assuming “the backward indexation of prices” in “a mechanical way”
which amplifies Keynesian aggregate demand effects of policy.
VII. Impacts of an Entire U.S. Stimulus Package
Although the simulations in this paper have focussed on government spending
multipliers in the case of changes in government purchases of goods and services, it is
possible to say something about the impact of a the broader U.S. fiscal stimulus package,
which also includes tax rebates and one-time transfer payments to individuals. For this
purpose we focus on the impact in the fourth quarter of 2010 where the size of the increased
government purchases (including 60 percent of transfers to states and localities for this
purpose) is .73 percent of GDP and the impact on GDP is .46 percent, implying a multiplier in
that quarter of .63 (=.46/.73). We choose this quarter for two reasons. First, as shown in
Figure 2, it is close to the quarter of maximum GDP impact, so by choosing this quarter we
will in no way be understating the results. In fact, the impact declines sharply after this
quarter. Second, this is the quarter for which Romer and Bernstiein (2009) report their
16
widely-cited calculation that the fiscal stimulus package of February 2009 will increase GDP
by 3.6 percent and employment by 3-1/2 million. Hence, the last quarter of 2010 is useful for
comparison purposes.
As Table 3 shows, the deficit (excluding interest payments) increases by more than the
increase in government purchases in fiscal year 2009 through 2011. The lion’s share of the
difference between the deficit and purchases, 80 percent, consists of temporary tax rebates
and entitlement benefits for unemployment insurance, Medicaid benefits, health insurance
subsidies, and cash welfare payments. The fourth quarter of 2010 (calendar year) is the first
quarter of fiscal year 2011. In fiscal year 2011, the deficit minus purchases is $41 billion
(=134-93=41). However, this is a large decrease from fiscal year 2010 where the difference is
$246 billion (400-154=246). So for the purpose of estimating the impact of the broader
package in 2010Q4 (calendar) we take the average of fiscal year 2010 and 2011, or the
average of 41 and 246, which is $144 billion or about 1 percent of GDP.
How much of this “non-government-purchases” increase in the deficit should we add
to government purchases to compute the impact on GDP? To the extent that the tax rebates
and transfers to individuals are temporary, permanent income theory, even in the presence of
liquidity effects, says that the impact on consumption and thereby aggregate demand will be
small. Although there is a great deal of uncertainty, a review of the literature over the years
suggests that the marginal propensity to consume for such tax and transfer payments is at
most 0.3, though it will depend on timing, expectations, and other factors. Recent aggregate
evidence suggests that it may be much smaller. For example, an examination of the
Economic Stimulus Act of 2008 indicates that the impact of the tax rebates on consumption
was insignificantly different from zero.
10
Transfers to individuals, such as entitlement
payments for unemployment compensation, and health and welfare benefits, could be
expected to have an effect on consumption similar to temporary tax rebates. Although such
10
The estimated regression coefficients reported in Taylor (2009) are not statistically different from zero.
17
payments may temporarily boost household income, they also create employer incentives for
layoffs and for household members to delay their return to work. In sum, in our view, a
coefficient of .3 for the impact of these tax and transfers payments on consumption is likely
an upper bound and certainly a generous assumption about the size of the impact.
In any case, by assuming that the impact on consumption of the extra 1 percent
discretionary increase in the deficit is .3 percent of GDP and using the above mentioned
multiplier of .63 the impact will be to increase GDP by an additional .19 percent. If we add
this to the .46 percent GDP increase from purchases, the total impact will be to increase GDP
by.65 percent in the fourth quarter of 2010 compared to what it would otherwise be.
Romer and Bernstein (2009) calculated that the impact of the 2009 stimulus package
would be to raise GDP by 3.6 percent by the fourth quarter of 2010, which is 6 times greater
than our calculation based on the new Keynesian model simulations of the impact of
purchases and a generous assessment of the impact of tax rebates and temporary transfers.
Romer and Bernstein (2009) also give an estimate of the increase employment from
the fiscal package. They assume an additional 1 million jobs for each 1 percent increase in
real GDP. Thus they estimate an increase of 3-1/2 million jobs as a result of the fiscal policy
package enacted in February 2009. Using the same method our estimate is closer to ½ million
additional jobs. To put that smaller number into perspective it is less than the 598 thousand
payroll jobs lost in the single month of January 2009 while the fiscal policy packages were
being debated.
Romer and Bernstein also report job estimates in a number of private sector industries
which would have to be radically scaled down if the numbers we have calculated are correct.
In addition, our finding of crowding out of private consumption and investment due to the
increase in government purchases raises doubts about the estimate that 90 percent of the jobs
will be created in the private sector. Indeed, with the impact of government purchases on
18
GDP (.46) nearly three times greater than the impact of tax rebates and transfers on GDP
(.19), a net decline in private sector jobs is likely.
VIII. Conclusion
In this paper we used a modern empirical approach to estimate government spending
multipliers, and we contrasted these multipliers with those that have recently been used in
practice to analyze fiscal policy in the United States. We focused on an empirically estimated
macroeconomic model—the Smets-Wouters model—recently published in the American
Economic Review. As attested by leading macroeconomic researchers, such as Michael
Woodford in his recent survey, this model well represents new Keynesian macroeconomic
thinking of the kind that many macroeconomists now teach their graduate students and use in
their research.
We find that the government spending multipliers from permanent increases in federal
government purchases are much less in new Keynesian models than in old Keynesian models.
The differences are even larger when one estimates the impacts of the actual path of
government purchases in fiscal packages, such as the one enacted in February 2009 in the
United States or similar ones discussed in other countries. The multipliers are less than one as
consumption and investment are crowded out. The impact in the first year is very small. And
as the government purchases decline in the later years of the simulation, the multipliers turn
negative.
The estimates reported here of the impact of such packages are in stark contrast to
those reported in the paper by Christina Romer and Jared Bernstein. They report impacts on
GDP for a broad fiscal package that are six times larger than those implied by government
spending multipliers in a typical new Keynesian model and our calculations based on
generous assumptions of the impacts of tax rebates and transfers on GDP. They also report
job estimates that are six times larger than these alternative models, and the impacts on
19
private sector jobs are likely to be at variance with the alternative models by an even larger
amount. At the least, our findings raise serious doubts about the robustness of the models and
the approach currently used for practical fiscal policy evaluation.
20
References
Chari, V.V., Patrick Kehoe, and Ellen McGrattan, (2009), “New Keynesian Models: Not Yet
Useful for Policy Analysis,” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, Vol. 1,
No. 1, 242-266.
Coenen, Guenter and Roland Straub (2005), “Does Government Spending Crowd in Private
Consumption? Theory and Empirical Evidence for the Euro Area,” International
Finance, 8(3): 435-470.
Congressional Budget Office, “Cost Estimate for Conference Agreement for H.R.1”, February
13, 2009.
Christiano, Lawrence J., Martin Eichenbaum, and Charles L. Evans (2005), “Nominal
Rigidities and the Dynamic Effects of a Shock to Monetary Policy,” Journal of
Political Economy, 113(1): 1-45.
Gali, Jordi, David Lopez-Salido, Javier Valles (2007), “Understanding the Fffects of
Government Spending on Consumption,” Journal of the European Economic
Association, 5(1), 227-270.
Romer, Christina and Jared Bernstein (2009), “The Job Impact of the American Recovery and
Reinvestment Plan.” January 8, 2009.
Thomas J. Sargent and Neil Wallace (1975), “Rational Expectations, the Optimal Monetary
Instrument, and the optimal Money Supply Rule,” Journal of Political Economy 83,
241–254.
Smets, Frank and Raf Wouters (2007), "Shocks and Frictions in U.S. Business Cycles: A
Bayesian DSGE Approach." American Economic Review 97, 3: 506–606.
Taylor, John B. (1993), Macroeconomic Policy in a World Economy: From Econometric
Design to Practical Operation, WW Norton, New York.
21
Taylor, John B. (2009), “The Lack of an Empirical Rationale for a Revival of Discretionary
Fiscal Policy,” American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, (May) Vol. 99,
No. 2.
Taylor, John B. and Volker Wieland (2008), "Surprising Comparative Properties of Monetary
Models," working paper.
Wieland, Volker, Tobias Cwik, Gernot Mueller, Sebastian Schmidt and Maik Wolters (2009),
"A New Comparative Approach to Macroeconomic Modelling and Policy Analysis"
Manuscript, Center for Financial Studies, Frankfurt.
Woodford, Michael (2009), “Convergence in Macroeconomics: Elements of the New
Synthesis, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, Vol. 1, No. 1, 267-279.