DOCUMENT RESUME
ED 074 884
HE 003 682
AUTHOR
.
Woodhall, Maureen
TITLE
Financing 'Students in Higher Education:'Educational,
Social and Economic Implications of Alternative
Methods of Finance.
INSTITUTION
United Nations Educational, Scientific, and Cultural
Organization, Paris (France). International Inst. for
Educational Planning.
REPORT NO
IIEP-TM-42-69
PUB CATE
[69]
NOTE
13p.; Paper in The Fundamentals of Educational
Planning: Lecture-Discussion Series
EDRS PRICE
MF-$0.65 HC-$3.29
DESCRIPTORS
*Educational Finance; *Educational Planning;
Financial, Support; *Higher Education; Public Support;
*Scholarship Loans; Student Costs; *Student Loan
Programs
ABSTRACT
This lecture is part of "Fundamentals of. Educational
Planning; Lecture-Discussion Series,"
a controlled experiment aiming
at the development of efficient teaching materials in the, field of'
educational planning.'The author discusses (1) the justification for
public subsidy of higher education;
(2)
methods of subsidizing
students;
(3) the objective of student aid programs;
(4) grants
versus loans for students; and (5) 'the evaluation of systems of
student aid. In addition, reading materials
are suggeSted for those
who wish to pursue the topic further.
(HS)
FILMED FROM BEST AVAILABLE COPY
CO
co
Ca
The Fundamentals of Educational Planning
Lecture
Discussion Series
No 42 FINANCING STUDENTS IN HIGHER EDUCATION:
EDUCATIONAL, SOCIAL AND ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS
OF ALTERNATIVE METHODS OF FINANCE
by Maureen Woodhall
U.S DEPARTMENT
OF HEAL.
rH.
EDUCATION
& WELFARE
FFE OF
EDUCATION
THIS DoOCICUMENT
HAS BEEN
REPRO
DUCED
EXACTLY
AS RECEIVED
FROM
THE PERSON
OR OHCANIZA1TION
ORIG
INA TING
IT POINTS
OT 111/,'W OR 0711N
IONS STA1ED
DO tl:
NECESSAFT/LY
REPRESENT
OFFICIAL
OFFICE
OF EDU
CAT/ON
POST HON
OR POLICY
Unesco :
International Institute for Educational Planning
co
co,
IIEP/TM/42/69
INTERNATIONAL INSTITUTE FOR EDUCATIONAL PLANNING
9, rue Eugene Delacroix.
Paris 16e, France
FINANCING STUDENTS IN MOM EDUCATION:
EDUCATIONAL, SOCIAL AND ECONOMIC IMPLICATIONS
OF ALTERNATIVE METHODS OF FINANCE
by
Maureen Woodhall
This lecture is part of 'Fundamentals of Educational Planning;
Lecture-Discussion Series' a controlled-experiment undertaken by the
International Institute for Educational Planning in collaboration with a
limited number of organizations'ind individuals aiming at the development
of efficient teaching materials in the field of educational planning.
By
their very nature these materials, whichdraw upon tape recordings, trans-
criptions- and summary notes of seminars, lectures and discussions conducted
by IIEP as part of, its training and research programme, are informal and
not subjectto the type of editing customary for psublished:docuMents
They
are therefore not to be Considered as lofficialpublleations'
The opinions expressed in this lecture are thoSe of the author and
do not necessarily:represent 'the:views-of the Institute.
IIEP/TM/42/69
CONTENTS
Pqft
1.
The justification for public subsidy of higher education
1
2.
Methods of sUbsidizing-students
3
3.
The objective of student aid programmes
4_
4.
Grants versus loans for students
6
5.
The evaluation of systems of student aid
8
Suggested Additional Reading
10
IIEP /TM/k2 /69 - page 1
1.
The justification for public subsidy of higher education
In recent years the rapid expansion of higher education throughout
the world has emphasized the problems of financing
the most expensive level
Of educatiOn,
Costs per student in higher education tend to be
very much
higher than costs per pupil at any other level of
education. In most
countries higher education is financed by a combination
of public and
private sources of funds.
Even if universities do not charge tuition fees,
the student himself normally bears
a considerable part of the total
resource cost of education in the form of the earnings forgone while he
continues his education, instead of joining the labour
market. These
forgone earnings represent one of the costs of higher
education both to the
individual - who loses income he would have' received
if he were not a
student 7 and to the community -which loses the
output the student would
have produced if he had joined the labour market.
On the other hand, even
if universities do' charge fes these generally do
not 'represent the full
'costs of tuition, so that some form of subsidy
is required to finance the
current and'capital expenditure of universities.
The question of how higher education should be financed,
and what
should be-the balance between public and private
contributions raises a
number of issues.
For example:, what level and form should public
subsidy
of education take and what is the justification
for this subsidy;
should
financial assistance be giveh directly to institutions
of higher education,
to enable them to reduce or abolish fees,
or to students, to,enable them
to pay, fees;
should public subsidies for higher education
be financed, out
of general taxation or in some other way?
This paper is concerned with
the issue of financial aid forstudents:
what are the objectives of
student aid schemes in different countries;
what form and level does
financial assistance take;
what are the criteria for selecting students for
aid;
and finally how should alternative systems
of student aid be
evaluated?
But since financial aid to students is'only::one form
of public subsidy
of highe.r education., it is interesting to consider
first the ;justification
for subsidization of higher education out of
;public funds.
The main economic,
justificatiOnforproyiding publid;:financejor
any service is that society
aS a whole deriVes somenefitfrom the
Servic0.,
and
.:that
would be
neglectedlor reduced if,it:were leftentirely to
priVate individualS,to finance
it
Thus subsidy of higher educatiOn,JS JUStified,bY:the
argument,:that it
producesbothHedonomicandsocial benefits for society, including highly
qualified, manpower, cultural and aesthetic values,
ac.
lions tojIhmanknowledge,
and.So,on..: Itjs, recognised that higher, education
al;
pr06:,.irecteconomi0
andnorp7eConOmid benefits:forthe:educated
individuals themSelVeS,'butthe
case.fOr:,publid,SUbbidyrests';onthe
belief-thatthebenefits to society exceed
theipenefitsto*indiViduals.,
IIEP/TM/42/69 - page 2
There is another argument for public subsidy of higher education.
If
opportunities for higher education were given only to those who could afford
to pay for it, it would be both inefficient and inequitable.
It would be
inefficient because some of the most able students would not be able to
afford to continue their education, and it would be inequitable because
higher education confers benefits on the individual in the form of better job
opportunities and higher lifetime earnings, so that to distribute education
in accordance with individuals' purchasing power would mean preserving and
exaggerating inequalities of income in the future.
Thus the subsidy of higher education out of public funds has both an
economic and a social justification.
The next question that must be answered
is what form the subsidy should take, and how it should-be financed.
The
following table summarizes various possible ways of subsidizing higher
education.
Table 1.
Alternative methods of financing and subsidizing higher education
Methods of subsidy
Methods of financing
1. Direct subsidy to institutions to
eliminate or reduce fees
2. Direct subsidy to students in the
form Of unconditional grants
3. Direct subsidy to selected students
in the form, of means- tested grants,
scholarships
or bursaries
4. Direct:subsidy to students; in, the
form of guaranteed:loans at
interest:
rates
5.- Direct subsidy to studentSHin the
form Of: specially provided part7
time paid eMploymentor meals and
accommodation at prides below
market pricet
....11.==1.1,-T.
1. General taxation of income (at
central or local level)
2. General taxation of expenditure
e.g. sales tax, excise duties
(at central or local level)
3. Special taxation of graduates'
.incomes
. Loan repayments of past students
6.: Direct subsidy m parents or:'to
graduates in employment, in the
jOrm of tax:condessiOns:feir edu-
cationaiexpenditUres
IIEP/TM/42/69 - page 3
2.
methods of subsidizing students
Most countries ,subsidize higher education by means of
a combination of
direct payments to institutions, to cover capital and current
expenses, and
payments to some individual students, to
cover fees where necessary, and also
living expenses.
The payments to students take different forms in different
countries.
Many countries, both developed and developing, have scholarship
schemes under which grants are made to selected students, chosen either
on
the basis of ability or of financial need.
These grants are sometimes
unconditional, as for example in the United Kingdom, where all students who
gain admission to a university are eligible for consideration for
a grant,
although the amount a student receives is subject to
a means test, and thus
determined by the level of his parents' income.
Alternatively, the grant
may be subject to certain conditions, for example in Ghana students receive
grants on the condition that they work for the government
on graduation.
A number of countries, both developed and developing, give
some aid
to students in'the form of repayable loans, with
or without interest, rather
than outright grants.
Loans now constitute some part'of the finance of
higher education 'in at least ten advanced.countries, U.S.A.,
Canada, Japan,
Australia, Sweden, Norway, Denmark, Finland, Western Germany and
the Netherlands, and a number of developing countries, including
India,
Kenya, Colombia, Venezuela, Peru and thelDominican
Republic,
Another form of financial assistance 4.:;o students is specially
prOvided.part-time paid employment,
Many American universities have'for
some time operated private schemes of this sort, and in 1964 the Federal
Government set up the College. Work.Study Programme, which provides
Federal
funds to colleges and universities to enable them to expand job oPpor-
tunities for students.
The proportion of students receiving direct aid varies considerably
between countries.
In some developing countries less than 3 per cent of
students in higher education receive any form of scholarship, whereas in
the U.K. and Scandinavian countries over 70
per cent of students receive
some direct aid.
A survey carried out in 1959-60 for the international
Study of University Admissions showed that taking all
countries together,
32.9 per cent of students in higher education in developed
countries
received direct aid, and 8.7 per cent in less developed countries.
Table '2 summarizes the proportion of students receiving
aid in ko
countries.
IIEP/TM/42/69 - page 4
Table 2.
Percentage of students receivingdirect aid in various countries
Nil
0-3 4-8
9-15
16-30
31-50
51-100
Developed countries
Less developed coun-
tries
6
3
11
5
4
1
1
Total
114-
9
3
1
Finally, most countries provide indirect subsidies to students, as well
as making some direct payments.
It is difficult to obtain accurate data on
levels of expenditure on indirect aid, since it is sometimes financed by
ministries other than the Ministry of Education, but
no review of financial
aid to students would be complete without consideration of expenditure on
housing, food and.traVel subsidies and medical and welfare expenditures:
3o
The objectives of student
Student aid schemes in different countries may have a number of different
objectives.
The International Study of University Admissions, conducted by
Unesco and the. International Association of Universities, included a brief
review of financial aid schemes for students, and classified the schemes into
four main categories:
(a) 'seed-bed.' schemes, generally found in the poorest and educationally
most backward. countrieso, Such schemes provide aid for a handful
of students, and their main purpose is to promote a rapid expansion
of education at a later date;
(b) Ymanpower
schemes, whose chief aim is to provide aid to meet a
country's requireMentS for various types of skilled manpower;
(c)
' equalization' schemes,: whiCh are concerned with increasing and
equalising educational; opportunities) and-their main purpose is
to ensure that no ablestudent it preVented from continuing his
education by financial. need;
(d) 'salary' schemes, under which aid is given to all students,
regardless of their own or their pal,entslMeans, and thus aid,
becoMes) in effect.e:salarTpaid by the Stateto all Students.
IMP/TM/42/69 - page 5
These four categories demonstrate that different student aid schemes
may be intended to fulfill different objectives.
For example, the objective
of 'manpower' schemes is primarily economic, while 'equalisation' schemes
have a mainly social justification.
This method of classification is il-
luminat ing but unfortunately there
are few student aid schemes that can be
neatly classified in terms of a single category.
In most countries, student
aid policy has a number of different objectives, including economic, social
and educational aims.
When administrators of State student aid schemes are
asked what is the main purpose of student aid, they may reply
to encourage
demand for education' or
to equalise educational opportunities', 'to ensure
a sufficient supply of highly qualified manpower for the labour force' or
'to allow students to use their time in the most instructive way, so that they
are not forced to work part time or to interrupt their studies, because of
financial difficulties'.
In fact, in most countries student aid is intended
to satisfy all these objectives at once, which makes it difficult to eva]uate
fully most student aid schemes, because their aims are so diverse.
For example, in the U.S.A. there are two State subsidized loan schemes
for university students, the National Defense Student Loan Program and the
Guaranteed Loan :.rogram for Higher Education.
The purpose of these schemes is
to provide low interest loans for students in low-income or middle-income
families, to enable them to continue their education.
Thus one of the main
objectives of the scheme is, the equalisation of educational opportunity.
But
one particular characteristic of the National Defense Student Loan Program
has an economic justification:
to encourage graduates to enter the teaching
profession, in order to overcome a teacher shortage.
Graduates who do enter
teaching are forgiven part of the repayment obligation;
any teacher has
10 per cent of his loan repayment obligation cancelled for each year of
service as a full-time teacher, while teachers in low-income areas, or
teachers of handicapped children have 15 per cent cancelled for each year's
service.
Thus, this particular student aid scheme has both an 'equalisation'
and a 'manpower' element.
The fact that stUdent aid schemes have many,different objeCtives is
very important when attempting to evaluate theeffeCtiveness of student aid
policy.
If the:adM of financial: assistance is simply to increase demand for
higher education, ajirst assessment of its, effectiveness,can be made by
looking at enrolmentfiguret.;, But if the aim Of student aid is to equalise
opportunity it is necessary to have information on the social class background
of students, and tcloexAmip..-trends:in social class participation rates in
higher education.
The effect of student aid policy on educational efficiency
must alsobe judgekin the light of the effetts:of.financialassistance on
students'proPensity to part time WorkOnthe:averagelength::Ofstudy and on
wastagerates::inihigher: education*
Thusanyttudent didiolicy must be:
evaluatedin::terms of its eConomici,'socie.):andedUcational implications.: In
the following section we will examine some of the implications of two
alternative methods of SubSidizingitudents
by'meantof outright grants
and scholarshipss Or:bTmeans: of repayable loans,
IIEP/TM/69 - page 6
4,
Grants versus loans for students
Loans have been justified by some writers as a means of financing students
for a number of reasons.
At the same time other writers have attacked the idea
of loans, and argued for a system of outright grants.
The arguments can be briefly
summarized under five headings:
(a) The supply of finance for higher education
Economists in Britain and the U.S.A. have argued for the use of loans to
finance students on the grounds that this will increase the overall supply of
finance for higher education.
In the short-run it makes little difference,
whether financial aid is given in the form of grants or loans, since funds must
be found to make the initial payments to students.
On the other hand in the
long-run there is a saving of public funds if the student is required to repay
all or part of the loan.
The extent of the saving depends on the, period of
time which graduates are allowed, in order to repay, and the interest 14hich
they must pay.
Many loan schemes, for example in Scandinavia, provide interest
free or low interest loans.
In Denmark, for example, students receive aid in
the form of 50 per cent grant, 50 per cent interest-free loan;
in Norway,
interest is charged at 4 3/4 per cent.
Thus the saving involved in the loan
scheme is less than if full commercial rates of interest were charged, but
some
saving of public funds is nevertheless achieved.
Another possible way in which
a loan scheme may increase the supply of finance for higher education is by
tapping private sources of finance.
For example, in Finland, and in the
U.S.A. under the Guaranteed Loan Program, the initial loan for a student is
provided by private banks, but under a government guarantee.
In such cases
the government subsidizes the interest on the loan, and meets the cost of
cancellation of loans in cases of hardship or illness, or in the event of a
graduate defaulting, but public funds are not required to finance the initial
payments to students.
Thus loans are often justified as a means of overcoming
one of the long-term constraints on the development of student aid:
a
shortage of public revenue.
(b) The benefits of higher education
Advocates of loans argue that since higher education confers financial
benefits on the edUcated, graduates should:repay part of the,coSt of their':
education out of the higher:Iifetime earnings they enjoy as
a result of 'thiS
education
On the:Other:handadvocates of:.grants frequentlyargUe, that
society as a whole benefits in botheconoMic and non
- economic terms, from
higher education; and the'supplY'of highly qualified manpower,,So that
society as a whole:SY,Iouldfinancehighereducation'Outof"generaltaxation
In fact:the .:1benefi.t principle:of taxation
that he whobenefitsfrom a
serviceshould':prOvide the finance for that Seryipeean::be uSedt6Hsupport
private payments and publieSbSidy,sincehighereducationprovidesbenefits
bOth for the :individualand: fOrsodietY. *Iopmbia,the COlombian'Institute
for AdvancedTtaining Abroad:(ICETEX) which:administers aid torstudentĀ§'
IIEP/TM/42/69 - page 7
higher education both in Colombia and abroad,
gives loans ratherthan scholar-
ships, on the grounds that 'education is good business, the
profit reaped, by
the student being commensurate with the capital invested'.
On the other
hand many scholarship schemes are justified in terms of the
contribution made
by highly qualified graduates to national income, the country's
need for
qualified manpower, and the indirect
or 'spillover' benefits generated by
investment in higher education,
The disagreement between advocates of loans
and of grants is essentially over the degree of subsidy required
to ensure
optimum investment in higher education from the point of view
of society.
(c) Equity and equality of opportunity
Closely linked with arguments about, the benefits of higher
education
are arguments abOut the equity of alternative methods of finance,
Loan
advocates argue that loans are more equitable than grants,
since graduates,
who earn more than average as a result of their education,
provide finance
themselves, by repaying loans out of these higher than
average earnings,
whereas a grant scheme involves a transfer of income from
the general
taxpayer with average or below average earnings to those who
will have high
lifetime earnings.
On the other hand oPponents of loans argue that the need
to repay loans will discourage working class students from
entering higher
education, and that grants will be more successful in equalising
educational
opportunity,
(d) The efficiency of higher education
Grants are often justified on the grounds that freedom from
financial
worry allows the student to work hard, and that fears of incurring large debts
may force students to take up.part-time work or even to drop out of higher
education before completing their courses.
In fact part-time work among
studentS is a common phenomenon in many countries,
but explanations for this
are closely linked with the way university courses are organiSed, the length
of time needed for a degree and similar characteristics
in the structure of
higher education.
There is little direct evidence on the relationship
between methods of financing students, and length of, study
or patterns of
part-time employment.
) Practical problems of
administering a loan scheme
Sometimes loans are attacked as unfeasible because of
certain practical:
difficulties in implementing a loan scheme.
FOr:example, how is it poSsible to
make concessions to graduates who have low incomes
a result of illness,
unemployment
or the:::Ohoice of.lOwindomeoccuPations?
How,isHthe problem
of the married Womangraduatewho giveSAT working: to,be sOlVed
How:will
the authorities :,SolyeSudhPrOblems:AS.:non7rePaymenbtdefaulter0,.
or by
graduate's who emigrateI
fact, those coUntriehat:haVe adoptedjOan
Schemes'have:notfound.-such4voblemsto.beitisuperable. :J46st loan:schemes
include some element of ...'insurance', so;:that.:,gr4duateS
are ;permitted to
IIEP/TM/42/69 - page 8
postpone repayment in the case of financial hardship.
It is'true that a loan
scheme requires an efficient adminiStrative structure to ensure that repayments
are made regularly, and to deal with cases of hardship,
But in Scandinavia
the costs of administering the official loan schemz,s amount to only between
1 and 2 per cent of the total annual expenditure by the ilpvernment on student
aid.
5.
The evaluationofsystems of student aid
The aim of this brief paper has been to demonstrate that student aid
policy in different countries is intended to satisfy many different objectives,
and to show that there are alternative means of providing financial aid for
students.
Scholarships constitute one, but by no means the only, way of giving
direct financial assistance to students
Loans represent a feasible alternative,
and in some cases appear to be successful in.increasing the supply of finance
for higher educations
But it is sometimes claimed that this is at the expense
of certain undesirable consequences, particularly in discouraging working class
students.
In fact the reasons for low working class participation in higher
education are extremely complex, and the structure of the educational system,
methods of selection, and traditional attitudes must be analysed
as well as
methods of finance.
In order to evaluate loans as a method of financing higher education
information would be needed on such issues as:
(i) What is the extent of public subsidy of higher education?
(ii) What is the stated justification for this degree of subsidy?
(iii) Has there been any attempt to estimate the private and social
benefits of education?
(iv) What are the conditions of eligibility for loans?
(v) What are the terms of repayment?
(vi) What is.the average level of debt of university graduates;
at
the end of their course?
(vii) What is the extent of part-time employment
among students?
What evidence is there of the effect of loans
on part-time
employment?
(viii) What alternative forthe of finance are utilised by students?:"
IIEP /TM/k2 /69 - page 9
(ix) What is the
average length..
and rate of wastage among
students?
What evidence is there of the effect of loans
on
wastage or length of study?
(x) What is the social composition of the
student body?
(xi) What is the sex composition of the
student body?
(xii) What evidence is there
on the attitudes of women or working -
class students to loans?
(xlii) Are special concessions given to
graduates with low incomes or
to married women?
(xiv) What are the general attitudes of
students towards loans?
(xv) What are the costs of administration?
(xvi) What are the practical problems of
administration in a student'
loan scheme?
(xvii) Are there any built-in flexibilities
in the scheme, such as
favourable repayment terms for particular
groups of graduates?
(xviii) What are the financial savings
produced by aloansscheme?
(xix) What have been. the.-effects of changes in the method of
financing?
(xx) What proposals for reform of "che finance
of higher education have
been-put.-forward?-
These data would then need to be compared with similar data for
a
country operating a grant scheme, as opposed to
a loan scheme for students.
It would then be possible to evaluate loans and grants in
terms of the
objectives of student aid policy in each country.
Such an evaluation would require a major research project.
Some
information is available on loan schemes in the U.S.A. and
Scandinavia, and is
given in the bibliography.
But a full evaluation of alternative methods of
finance requires more information than is yet available.'
However,..the educational planner may gain some insights about the relative
merits of alternative methods of financeby analysing the
objectives of student,
aid. in his own country.
The International Study of University Admissions
con-
cluded its review of student aid with the observation:
IIEP/TM/42/69
page 10
'Few countries have decided what their aid
r'ogrammes should achieve.
It, is still rarer for this to be done in any detail
on the basis of
manpoWer studies, for instance.
AdminiStrative failure's and the posi7-'
tion of aid as:the poor relation among eduCational: problems'
also
meant thatrarely has the best possible use been madeofthe limited
funds available.
Aid schemes cannot be expected to
promote a
country's adUcational
economic or social developmentefficiency if,
as at present, no)?asii for their assessment end 'evaluation exists"-,
Some :progress,has been made, since the publication of that statement,-
towards the proper evaluation of alternative Methods of finance; but-Anore
research is needed, to ensure that
student aid policy is an effective instrument
for helping to achieve a Country's eduCatiOnal, social-and economic aims.
Suggested additional readinE
Edding F. 'Student Aid:
Concepts, Objectives.and Methods' in OECD, Financing
of Education for Economic Growth.
Paris:
OECD, 1966, pp, 251-264.
Eide Ke 'Some Financial Instruments and Efficiency
Incentives in Educational.
Policy' in OECD,:Bucro ammeAhal
sis anclCost-Effeotiveness in
Educational Planning, Paris:
OECD, 19
1).
15 71 5.
Harris S.
Higher Education:
Resources and Finance.
New York:
McGraw Hill,
1962.
KirkpatriCk J. A Stud
of Federal Student.Loarv,Pro rams.
Washington:
Government Printing Office, 19
.
,
Rivlin A.
The Role of the Federal Government in Financin Hi
er Education.
WashingtOn:
Brookings Institute, 1,
1.
Woodhall M. Student Loans as a Means of Financing
Higher Education:
A Review
of Scandinavian Experience.
Forthcoming, 1970.
Unesco/International Association of Universities:
Access to Higher Education
(ed. F. Bowles) VOL 1, Appendix
C, 'Direct Aid to Students'.
Paris:
Unesco/IAO, 1963.