24
Lessons for mitigation from the foundations
of monetary policy in the United States
Gary W. Yohe
24.1 Introduction
Many analysts, (including Pizer [Chapter 25], Keller et al.
[Chapter 28], Webster [Chapter 29] and Toth [Chapter 30] in
this volume, as well as others like Nordhaus and Popp [1997],
Tol [1998], Lempert and Schlesinger [2000], Keller et al.
[2004] and Yohe et al. [2004]) have begun to frame the debate
on climate change mitigation policy in terms of reducing the
risk of intolerable impacts. In their own ways, all of these
researchers have begun the search for robust strategies that are
designed to take advantage of new understanding of the climate
systems as it evolves an approach that is easily motivated by
concerns about the possibility of abrupt climate change sum-
marized by, among others, Alley et al. (2002). These concerns
take on increased importance when read in the light of recent
surveys which suggest that the magnitude of climate impacts
(see, for example, Smith and Hitz [2003]) and/or the likelihood
of abrupt change (IPCC, 2001; Schneider, 2003; Schlesinger
et al., 2005) could increase dramatically if global mean tem-
peratures rose more than 2 or 3
C above pre-industrial levels.
Neither of these suggestions can be advanced with high con-
fidence, of course, but that is the point. Uncertainty about the
future in a risk-management context becomes the fundamental
reason to contemplate action in the near term even if such
action cannot guarantee a positive benefit–cost outcome either
in all states of nature or in expected value.
Notwithstanding the efforts of these and other scholars to
reflect these sources of concern in their explorations of near-
term policy intervention, the call for a risk-management
approach has fallen on remarkably deaf ears. Indeed, uncer-
tainty is frequently used by many in the United States policy
community and others in the consulting business as the fun-
damental reason not to act in the near term. For evidence of
this tack, consider the policy stance of the Bush Administra-
tion that was introduced in 2002. In announcing his take on the
climate issue, the Presiden t emphasized that “the policy
challenge is to act in a serious and sensible way, given our
knowledge. While scientific uncertainties remain, we can
begin now to address the factors that contribute to climate
change” (www.whitehouse.gov/ new/releases/2002/02/climate
change.html; my emphasis). Indeed, the New York Times
reported on June 8th, 2005 that Philip Cooney, the White
House Council on Environmenta l Quality, repeatedly inserted
references to “significant and fundamental” uncertainties into
official documents that describ e the state of climate science
even though he has no formal scientific training (Revkin,
2005). In large measure responding to concerns about uncer-
tainty among his closest advisers, the President’s policy called
for more study, for voluntary restraint (by those motivated to
reduce their own emissions even thoug h others are not), and
for the development of alternatives to current energy-use
technologies (because reducing energy dependence is other-
wise a good idea even though promising advancements face
enormous difficulty penetrating the marketplace).
If productive dialogue is to resume, advocates of risk-based
near-term climate policy will have to express its value in terms
that policymakers will understand and accept. The case must
be made, in other words, that a risk-management approach to
near-term climate policy would be nothing more than the
application of already accepted policy-analysis tools and
principles to a new arena. This paper tries to contribute to this
process by turning for support to recent descriptions of how
Human-induced Climate Change: An Interdisciplinary Assessment, ed. Michael Schlesinger, Haroon Kheshgi, Joel Smith, Francisco de la Chesnaye, John M.
Reilly, Tom Wilson and Charles Kolstad. Published by Cambridge University Press. Ó Cambridge University Press 2007.
Human-Induced Climate Change : An Interdisciplinary Assessment, edited by Michael E. Schlesinger, et al., Cambridge University Press, 2007. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/wesleyan/detail.action?docID=321450.
Created from wesleyan on 2018-04-02 12:02:47.
Copyright © 2007. Cambridge University Press. All rights reserved.
monetary policy is conducted in the United States. Opening
remarks offered by Alan Greenspan, Chairman of the Federal
Reserve Board, at a symposium that was sponsored by the
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City in August 2003 are a
great place to start (Greenspan, 2003). In his attempt to
motivate three days of intense conversation among policy
experts, Chairman Greenspan observed:
For example, policy A might be judged as best advancing the pol-
icymakers’ objectives, conditional on a particular model of the
economy, but might also be seen as having relatively severe adverse
consequences if the true structure of the economy turns out to be
other than the one assumed. On the other hand, policy B might be
somewhat less effective under the assumed baseline model ... but
might be relatively benign in the event that the structure of the
economy turns out to differ from the baseline. These considerations
have inclined the Federal Reserve policymakers toward policies that
limit the risk of deflation even though the baseline forecasts from
most conventional models would not project such an event.
(Greenspan (2003), p. 4; my emphasis).
The Chairman expanded on this illustration in his pre-
sentation to the American Economic Association (AEA) at
their 2004 annual meeting in San Diego:
... the conduct of monetary policy in the United States has come to
involve, at its core, crucial elements of risk management. This con-
ceptual framework emphasizes understanding as much as possible the
many sources of risk and uncertainty that policymakers face, quan-
tifying those risks when possible, and assessing the costs associated
with each of the risks. ... ...This framework also entails, in light of
those risks, a strategy for policy directed at maximizing the prob-
abilities of achieving over time our goals ...Greenspan (2004), p. 37;
my emphasis).
Clearly, these views are consistent with an approach that
would expend some resources over the near term to avoid a
significant risk (despite a low probability) in the future.
Indeed, the Chairman used some familiar language when he
summarized his position:
As this episode illustrates (the deflation hedge recorded above), policy
practitioners under a risk-management paradigm may, at times, be led
to undertake actions intended to provide insurance against especially
adverse outcomes. (Greenspan (2004), p. 37; my emphasis).
So how did the practitioner s of monetary policy come to
this position? By some trial and error described by Greenspan
in his AEA presentation, to be sure; but the participants at
the earlier Federal Reserve Bank symposium offer a more
intriguing sourc e. Almost to a person, they all argued that the
risk-management approach to monetary policy evolved most
fundamentally from a seminal paper authored by William
Brainard (1967) ; see, for example, Greenspan (2003), Reinhart
(2003), and Walsh (2003).
This paper is crafted to build on their attribution by working
climate into Brainard’s modeling structure in the hope that it
might thereby provide the proponents of a risk-based approach
to climate policy some access to practitioners of macroeconomic
policy who are familiar with its structure and its evolution
since 1967. It does so even though the agencies charged with
crafting climate policy in the United States (the Department of
State, the Department of Energy, the Environmental Protec-
tion Agency, the Council for Environmental Quality, etc.) are
not part of the struct ure that crafts macroeconomic policy (the
Federal Reserve Board, the Treasury, the Council of Eco-
nomic Advisors, etc.). The hope, therefore, is really that the
analogy to monetary policy will spawn productive dialogue
between the various offices where different policies
are designed and implemented, even as it provides the envir-
onmental community with an example of a context within
which risk-management techniques have informed macroscale
policies.
The paper begi ns with a brief review of the Brainard (1967)
structure with and without a climate policy lever and proceeds
to explore the circumstances under which its underlying
structure might lead one to appropriately ignor e its potential.
Such circumstances can and will be identified in Sections 24.2
and 24.3, but careful inclusion of a climate policy lever makes
it clear that they are rare even in the simple Brainard-esque
policy portfolio. In addition, manipulation of the model con-
firms that the mean effectiveness of any policy intervention,
the variance of that effectiveness and its correlation with
stochastic influences on outcome are all critical characteristics
of any policy. Section 24.4 uses this insight as motivation
when the text turns to describing some results drawn from the
Nordhaus and Boyer (2001) DICE model that has been
expanded to accommodate profound uncertainty about the
climate’s temperature sensitivity to increases in greenhouse
gas concentrations. Concluding remarks use these results, cast
in terms of comparisons of several near-term policy alter-
natives, to make the case that creative and responsive climate
policy can be advocated on the basis of the same criteria that
led the Federal Reserve System of the United States to adopt a
risk-management approach to mone tary policy.
24.2 The Brainard model
The basic model developed by Brainard (1967) considers a
utility function on some output variable y (read GDP, for
example) of the form:
VðyÞ¼ðy y*Þ
2
; ð24:1aÞ
where y* represents the targeted optimal value. The function
V(y) fundamentally reflects welfare losses that would accrue if
actual outc omes deviate from the optimum. The correlation
between y and some policy variable P (read a monetary policy
indicator such as the discount rate, for example) is taken to be
linear, so
y ¼ aP þ ":
In specifying this relationship, a is a parameter that determines
the ability of policy P to alter output and " is an unobservable
Lessons for mitigation from US monetary policy 295
Human-Induced Climate Change : An Interdisciplinary Assessment, edited by Michael E. Schlesinger, et al., Cambridge University Press, 2007. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/wesleyan/detail.action?docID=321450.
Created from wesleyan on 2018-04-02 12:02:47.
Copyright © 2007. Cambridge University Press. All rights reserved.
random variable with mean
"
and variance
2
"
. The expected
value of utility is therefore
EfVðyÞg ¼ Efy
2
2yy* þðy*Þ
2
g
¼fEðy
2
Þ2y*EðyÞþðy*Þ
2
g
¼f
y
2
y
2
2y*
y
þðy*Þ
2
g
¼f
y
2
þð
y
y*Þ
2
g:
ð24:1bÞ
In this formulation, o f course,
2
y
and
y
represent the variance
and mean of y, respectively, given a policy intervention
through P and the range of possible realizations of a and ".
If the decisionmaker knew the value of parameter a ¼a
o
with certainty, then
2
y
¼
2
"
. Moreover, prescribing a policy P
c
such that
y
¼y* would max imize expected utility. In other
words,
P
c
¼fy*
"
g=a
o
ð24:2aÞ
In an uncertain world where a is known only up to its mean
a
and variance
2
a
, however,
y
¼
a
P þ
"
and
2
y
¼ P
2
2
a
þ
2
"
under the assumption that a and " are independently dis-
tributed. Brainard focused his attention primarily on estima-
tion uncertainty, but subsequent applications of his model
(see, for example, Walsh [2003]) have also recognized many
of the other sources that plague our understanding of the cli-
mate system model, structural, and contextual uncertainties,
to name just three.
The first-order condition that characterizes the policy P
u
that would maximize expected utility in this case can be
expressed as
@EfVðyÞg=@P ¼f2P
u
2
a
þ 2 ð
y
y*Þ
a
g
¼f2P
u
2
a
þ 2 ð
a
P þ y*Þ
a
0
Collecting terms,
P
u
¼fðy*
"
Þ
a
g=f
a
2
þ
2
a
g
¼ P
c
=
2
a
=
2
a
Þþ1g
ð24:2bÞ
under the assumption that the distribution of a is anchored
with
a
¼a
o
. Notice that P
u
¼P
c
if uncertainty disappears as
2
a
converges to zero. If
2
a
grows to infinity, however, p olicy
intervention becomes pointless and P
c
collapses to zero. In the
intermediate cases, Brainard’s conclusion of caution the
“principle of attenuation” to use the phrase coined by Reinhart
(2003) applies. More specifically, policy intervention should
be restrained under uncertainty about its effectiveness, at least
in comparison with what it would have been if its impact were
understood completely.
Reinhart (2003) and others have noted that considerable
effort has been devoted to exploring the robustness of the
Brainard insight in a more dynamic context where the loss
function associated with deviations from y* is not necessarily
symmetric. They note, for exampl e, that the existence of
thresholds for y < y* below which losses become more severe
at an increasing rate can lead to an intertemporal hedging
strategy that pushes policy further in the positive direction in
good times even at the risk of overshooting the targeted y*
with some regularity. Using such a strategy move s
"
higher
over time so that the likelihood of crossing the troublesome
threshold falls in subsequent periods. In the realm of monetary
policy, for example, concerns about deflation have defined the
critical threshold; in the realm of climate, the possibility of
something sudden and non-linear such as the collapse of the
Atlantic thermohaline circulation comes to mind as a critical
threshold to be avoided by mitigation.
Practitioners of monetary policy have also worried about
avoiding states of nature where the effectiveness of P can be
eroded, and so they have found a second reason to support the
sort of dynamic hedging just described. In these contexts, for
example, central bankers have expressed concern that the
ability of reductions in the interest rate to stimulate the real
economy can be severely weakened if rates have already fallen
too far. In the climat e arena, decisionmakers may worry that it
may become impossible to achieve certain mitigation targets
over the long run if near-term interventions are too weak. This
point is illustrated in Yohe et al. (2004) when certain tem-
perature targets become infeasible if nothing is done over the
next 30 years to reduce greenhouse gas emissions.
Both of these concerns lie at the heart of the Greenspan
comparison of two policies, of course. However, neither
confronts directly the question at hand: under what circum-
stances (if any) can the effects of climate change on the real
economy be handled by standard economic interventions
without resorting to direct mitigation of the drivers of that
change?
24.3 Extending the model to include a climate
module
To address this question, we add a climate module to the
Brainard model so that we can search for conditions under
which it would make sense for policymakers who have their
hands on the macro-policy levers (the P in the basic model) to
ignore climate policy when they formul ate their plans. To that
end, we retain the symmetric utility function recorded in Eq.
(24.1a), but we add a new policy variable C (read mitigation
for the moment) to the output relationship so that
y ¼ aP þ cC þ ":
The error term " now includes some reflection of climate risk
to the output variable. Since the expected value of utility is
preserved, perfect certainty about a and now c still guarantees
that
2
y
¼
2
"
so that prescribing a policy P
c
such that
y
¼y*
would still maximize expected utility depicted by Eq. (24.1b).
Yohe296
Human-Induced Climate Change : An Interdisciplinary Assessment, edited by Michael E. Schlesinger, et al., Cambridge University Press, 2007. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/wesleyan/detail.action?docID=321450.
Created from wesleyan on 2018-04-02 12:02:47.
Copyright © 2007. Cambridge University Press. All rights reserved.
In other words,
P
c
¼fy*
"
g=a
o
would persist and the optimal intervention could be achieved
without exercising the climate policy variable. In this certainty
case, clearly, climate policy coul d be set equal to zero without
causing any harm.
In an uncertain world where a and c are known only up to
means (
a
and
c
) and variances (
2
a
and
c
2
), however, we
now have
y
¼
a
P þ
c
C þ
"
and
y
2
¼ P
2
2
a
þ C
2
c
2
þ
2
"
under the assumption that a, c and " are all independently dis-
tributed. We already know that this sort of uncertainty can
modify the optimal policy intervention, but does it also influence
the conclusion that the climate policy lever could be ignored?
24.3.1 The climate lever in an isolated policy
environment
To explore this question, note that Eq. (24.2b) would still
apply for setting policy P if the policymaker chose to ignore
the climate policy variable; i.e.,
P
uo
¼ P
u
¼ P
c
=
2
a
=
2
a
Þþ1g:
As a result, the first-order condition characterizing the policy
C
uo
that would maximize expected utility can be expressed as
@EfVðyÞg=@C ¼f2C
uo
c
2
þ 2ð
"
y* þ
a
P
u
þ
c
C
uo
Þ
c
0
Collecting terms,
C
uo
¼f½
2
a
2
c
=½D
a
D
c
gfðy*
"
Þ=
c
g; ð24:3Þ
where
D
a
f
2
a
þ
2
a
g and D
c
f
2
c
þ
2
c
g:
Notice that C
uo
¼0 if uncerta inty about the effectiveness of P
disappeared as
2
a
converged to zero. The climate policy lever
could therefore still b e ignored even in the context of uncer-
tainty drawn from our understanding of the climate system, in
this case. This would not mean, however, that climate change
should be ignored. The specification of P
uo
would recognize
the effect of climate through its effect on
"
.
If
2
a
grew to infinity, however, then l’Hospital’s rule shows
that policy intervention through C would dominate. Indeed, in
this opposing extreme case,
C
uo
¼fðy *
"
Þ=
c
g=
2
c
=
2
c
Þþ124:4Þ
so that policy intervention through C would mimic the original
intervention through P while P
uo
collapsed to zero. In the
more likely intermediate cases in which the variances of both
policies are non-zero but finite, the optimal setting for climate
policy would be positive as long as
c
> 0.
It follows, from consideration of the intermediate cases,
that bounded uncertainty about the effectiveness o f both
policies can play a critical role in determi ning the relative
strengths of climate and macroeconomic policies in the
policy mix. Put another way, uncertainty about the effec-
tiveness of either or both policies becomes the reason to
diversify the intervention portfolio by undertaking some
climate policy even if the approach taken in formulating
other policies remains unchanged. Moreover, the smaller
the uncertainty about the link between climate policy C
and output, the larger should be the reliance on climate
mitigation.
24.3.2 The climate lever in an integrated policy
environment
These observations fall short of answering the question of how
best to integrate macroeconomic and climate policy in an
optimal intervention portfolio. Maximizing expected utility if
both policies were considered together in a portfolio approach
would produce two first-order conditions:
@EfVðyÞg=@P ¼f2P
u
T
2
a
þ 2ð
"
y* þ
a
P
uT
þ
c
C
uT
Þ
a
0 and
@EfVðyÞg=@C ¼f2C
u
T
2
c
þ 2ð
"
y*
þ
a
P
uT
þ
c
C
uT
Þ
c
0:
In recording these conditions, P
uT
and C
uT
represent the
jointly determined optimal choices for P and C, respectively.
Solving simultaneously and collecting terms,
P
uT
¼f½
2
c
2
a
=½D
a
D
c
2
a
2
c
gfðy*
"
Þ=
a
g; and
ð24:5aÞ
C
uT
¼f½
2
a
2
c
=½D
a
D
c
2
a
2
c
gfðy
"
Þ=
c
g: ð24:5bÞ
Table 24.1 shows the sensitivities of these policies to extremes
in the characterizations of the distributio ns of the parameters a
and c . Notice that the policy specifications recorded in Eq.
(24.5a and b) collapse to the certainty cases for C and P if the
variance of c or a (but not both) collapses to zero, respectively.
The policies also converge to the characterizations in Eq.
(24.2b) or (24.4) if the variances of a or c grow without bound,
respectively (again by virtue of l’Hospital’s rule). In between
these extremes, Eq. (24.5a and b) show how ordinary eco-
nomic and climate policies can be integrated to maximize
expected utility. In this regard, it is perhaps more instructive to
contemplate their ratio:
fC
uT
=P
uT
g¼f½
2
a
c
=½
2
c
a
g: ð24:6Þ
Equation (24.6) makes it clear that climate policy should be
exercised relatively more vigorously if the variance of its
effectiveness parameter falls or if its mean effectiveness
Lessons for mitigation from US monetary policy 297
Human-Induced Climate Change : An Interdisciplinary Assessment, edited by Michael E. Schlesinger, et al., Cambridge University Press, 2007. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/wesleyan/detail.action?docID=321450.
Created from wesleyan on 2018-04-02 12:02:47.
Copyright © 2007. Cambridge University Press. All rights reserved.
increases. In addition, comparing Eq. (24.2b) and (24.5a)
shows that
fP
u
=P
uT
g¼fD
c
=
2
c
gþf
2
a
2
c
=
2
c
D
a
g> 1;
i.e., an integrated approach diminishes the role of ordinary
economic policy in a world that adds climate to the sources of
uncertainty to which it must cope as long as
c
2
is bounded.
It is, of course, possible to envision responsive climate
policy that corrects itself as our understanding of the climate
system evolves ramping up (or damping) the control if it
became clear that damages were more (less) severe than
expected and/or critical thresholds were closer (more distant)
than anticipated. In terms of the Brainard model, this sort of
properly designed responsive policy would create a negative
covariance between the effectiveness parameter c and the
random variable ". Since the variance of output is given by
2
y
¼ P
2
2
a
þ C
2
2
c
þ covðc; "Þþ
2
"
;
in this case, repeating the optimization exercise reveals that
P
0
uT
¼f½
2
c
2
a
=½D
a
D
c
2
a
2
c
gfðy
*
"
Þ=
a
g
þfcovðc; "Þ=D
a
g
¼ P
uT
þfcovðc; "Þ=D
a
g< P
uT
ð24:7aÞ
and
C
0
uT
¼f½
2
a
2
c
=½D
a
D
c
2
a
2
c
gfðy*
"
Þ=
c
g
fcovðc; "Þ=D
c
g
¼ C
uT
fcovðc; "Þ=D
c
g> C
uT
ð24:7bÞ
As should be expected, the ability of responsive climate policy
to deal more effectively with worsening climate futures would
increase its emphasis in an optimizing policy mix at the
expense of ordinary economic policy intervention.
24.3.3 Discussion
Equation (24.6) shows explicitly that an integrated policy
portfolio would ignore climate policies at its increasing peril,
especially if the design of the next generation of climate policy
alternatives could produce smaller levels of implementation
uncertainty. Targeting something closer to where impacts are
felt in the causal chain (like shooting for a temperature limit
rather than trying to achieve emissions pathways whose
associated impacts are known with less certainty) could, for
example, be preferred in the optimization framework if the
technical details of monitoring and reacting could be over-
come. As in any economic choice, however, there are tradeoffs
to consider. Moving to the impact end of the system should
reduce uncertainty on the damages side of the implementation
calculus (if monitoring, attribution, and response could all be
accomplished in a timely fashion, of course), but it could also
increase uncertainty on the cost side.
In any case, Eq. (24.7a and b) show that the potential
advantage of climate policy could turn on the degree to which
its design could accommodate a negative correlation. They
support consideration of a comprehensive climate policy that
could incorporate mechanisms at some level by which miti-
gation could be predictably adjusted as new scientific under-
standing of the climate system, climate impacts, and/or the
likelihood of an abrupt or non-linear change became available
(much in the same way that the rate of growth of the money
supply can be predictably adjusted in response to changes in
the overall health of the macroeconomy).
In addition, the same caveats discovered by the practitioners
of monetary policy certainly apply to the climate side of the
policy mix. Considering combined policies in a dynamic
context, that includes critical thresholds beyond which abrupt,
essentially unknown but potentially damaging impacts coul d
occur, would still support more vigorous intervention; and
climate policy should be particularly favored for this inter-
vention if it becomes more effective in avoiding those
thresholds when crossing their boundaries becomes more
likely. Indeed, the Greenspan warning can be especially telling
in these cases.
24.4 The hedging alternative under profound
uncertainty about climate sensitivi ty
The Brainard structure is highly abstract, to be sure, and so
conclusions drawn from its manipulation beg the question of
its applicability to the climate policy question as currently
formulated. This section confronts this question directly by
exercising a version of the Nordhaus and Boyer (2001) DICE
integrated assessment model that has been modified to
accommodate wide uncertainty in climate sensitivity and the
Table 24.1 Integrating policies in the extremes.
Limiting case C
uT
P
uT
c
2
!1 with 0 <
a
2
< 1 (i.e., D
c
!1) C
uT
!0 P
uT
!{( y* )/
a
}/{(
a
2
/
a
2
) þ1}
c
2
!0 with 0 <
a
2
< 8 1 (i.e., D
c
!
c
2
) C
uT
!{( y
*
"
)/
c
}P
uT
!0
a
2
!1 with 0 <
2
c
< 1 (i.e., D
a
!1) C
uT
!{( y
*
"
)/
c
}/ {(
2
c
/
2
c
) þ1} P
uT
!0
a
2
!1 with 0 <
2
c
< 1 (i.e., D
a
!
a
2
) C
uT
!0P
uT
! {( y*
"
)/
a
}
c
2
¼0 and
a
2
¼0 Undefined Undefined
Yohe298
Human-Induced Climate Change : An Interdisciplinary Assessment, edited by Michael E. Schlesinger, et al., Cambridge University Press, 2007. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/wesleyan/detail.action?docID=321450.
Created from wesleyan on 2018-04-02 12:02:47.
Copyright © 2007. Cambridge University Press. All rights reserved.
problem of setting near-term policy with the possibility of
making “midcourse” adjustments sometime in the future.
1
It
begins with a description of uncertainty in our current
understanding of climate sensitivity. It continues to describe
the modifications that were implemented in the standard DICE
formulation, and it concludes by reviewing the relative effi-
cacy, expressed in terms of expected net present value of gross
world (economic) product (GWP), of several near-term policy
alternatives.
24.4.1 A policy hedging exercise built around
uncertainty about climate sensitivity
Andronova and Schlesinger (2001) produced a cumulative
distribution of climate sensitivity based on the historical
record. Table 24.2 records the specific values of a discrete
version of this CDF that was used in Yohe et al. (2004) to
explore the relative efficacy of various near-term mitigation
strategies. There, the value of hedging in the near term was
evaluated under the assumption that the long-term objective
would constrain increases in global mean temperature to an
unknown target. Calibrating the climate module of DICE to
accommodate this range involved specifying both a climate
sensitivity and an associated parameter that reflects the inverse
thermal capacity of the atmospheric layer and the upper
oceans in its reduced-form representation of the climate sys-
tem. Larger climate sensitivities were correlated with smaller
values for this capacity so that the model could match
observed temperature data when run in the historical past. The
capacity parameter was defined from optimization of the
global temperature departures, calculated by DICE, and cali-
brated against the observed temperature departures from Jones
and Moberg (2003) for the prescribed range of the climate
sensitivities from 1.5 through 9
C.
It is widely understood that adopting a risk-management
approach means that near-term climate policy decisions
should, as a matter of course, recognize the possibility that
adjustments will be possible as new information about the
climate system emerges. The results that follow are the pro-
duct of experiments that recognize this understanding. Indeed,
they were produced by adopting the hedging environment that
was created under the auspices of the Energy Modeling Forum
in Snowmass to support initial investigations of the policy
implications of extreme events; Manne (1995) and Yohe
(1996) are examples of this earlier work. They were, more
specifically, drawn from a policy environment in which
decisionmakers evaluate the economic merits of implementing
near-term global mitigation policies that would be in force for
30 years beginning in 2005 under the assumption that all
uncertainty will be resolved in 2035. These global deci sion-
makers would, therefore, make their choices with the under-
standing that they would be able to “adjust” their interventions
in 2035 when they would be informed fully about both the
climate sensitivity and the best policy target. In making both
their initial policy choice and their subsequent adjustment,
their goal was taken to be maximizing the expected discounted
value of GWP across the range of options that would be
available at that time.
The hedging exercise required several struct ural and cali-
bration modifications of the DICE model in addition to
changes in the climate module that were described above.
Since responding to high sensitivities could be expected to put
enormous pressure on the consumption of fossil fuel, for
example, the rate of “decarbonization” in the economy
(reduction in the ratio of carbon emissions to global economic
output) was limited to 1.5% per year. Adjustments to miti-
gation policy were, in addition, most easily accommodated by
setting initial carbon tax rates in 2005 and again in 2035. The
initial and adjusted benchmarks appreciated annually at an
endogenously determined return to private capital so that
“investment” in mitigation was put on a par with investment in
economic capital. Finally, the social discount factor for GWP
included a zero pure rate of time preference in deference to a
view that the welfare of future generations should not be
diminished by the impatience of earlier generations for current
consumption.
24.4.2 Some results
Suppose, to take a first example of how the critical mean,
variance, and covariance variables from the Brainard foun-
dations might be examined, that global decisionmakers tried to
divine “optimal” intervention given the wide uncertainty about
climate sensitivity portrayed in Table 24.2. Table 24.3 dis-
plays the means and standard deviations of the net value,
expressed in terms of discounted value through 2200 and
computed across the discrete range of climate sensitivities
recorded in Table 24.2, for optimal policies that would
be chose n if each of the climate sensitivities recorded in
Table 24.2 Calibrating the climate module.
Climate sensitivity Likelihood Alpha-1 calibration
1.5 degrees 0.30 0.065742
2 degrees 0.20 0.027132
3 degrees 0.15 0.014614
4 degrees 0.10 0.011550
5 degrees 0.07 0.010278
6 degrees 0.05 0.009589
7 degrees 0.03 0.009157
8 degrees 0.03 0.008863
9 degrees 0.07 0.008651
Source: Yohe et al. (2004).
1
Climate sensitivity is defined as the increase in equilibrium global mean
temperature associated with a doubling of greenhouse gas concentrations
above pre-industrial levels, expressed in terms of CO
2
equivalents.
Lessons for mitigation from US monetary policy 299
Human-Induced Climate Change : An Interdisciplinary Assessment, edited by Michael E. Schlesinger, et al., Cambridge University Press, 2007. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/wesleyan/detail.action?docID=321450.
Created from wesleyan on 2018-04-02 12:02:47.
Copyright © 2007. Cambridge University Press. All rights reserved.
Table 24.2 were used to specify the uncontrolled baseline. The
mean returns of these interventions peak for the policy asso-
ciated with a 3
C climate sensitivity, but the standard devia-
tions grow monotonically with the assumed sensitivity.
Selecting the mean of these interventions produces a net
expected discounted value of $96.62 billion with a standard
deviation of $81.94 billion. The first row of Table 24.4 shows
the distribution of the underlying net values for this policy
across the range of climate sensitivities, and the second row
displays the associated maximum temperature increases that
correspond to each policy.
Now suppose that decisionmakers recognized that a policy
adjustment would be possible in 2035, but they could not tell
in 2005 which one would be preferred. The first row of Table
24.5 displays the corresponding net values under the
assumption that climate policy could be adjusted in the year
2035 to reflect the results of 30 years of research into the
climate system that would produce a complete understanding
of the climate sensitivity. In other words, the policy inter-
vention would respond to new information in 2035 to follow a
path that would then be optimal. The expected value of this
responsive policy, computed now with our current under-
standing as depicted in Table 24.2, climbs to $117.82 billion
(nearly a 22% increase), but the standard deviation also climbs
to $90.11 billion (nearly a 21% increase in variance). Looking
at Eq. (24.6) might suggest almost no change in the policy
mix, as a result, but comparing the second rows of Tables 24.4
and 24.5 would support, instead, an increased emphasis on a
climate-based intervention because the negative covariance of
such a policy and possible climate-based outcomes has grown
in magnitude (the relative value of climate policy has grown
significantly in the upper tail of the climate sensitivity dis-
tribution). Notice, though, that these adjustments have little
effect on the mean temperature increase; indeed, only the
standard deviation seems to be affected.
Given the wide range of temperature change sustained by
either “optimal” climate intervention, we now turn to
exploring how best to design a Greens pan-inspired hedge
against a critical threshold. If, to construct another example, a
3
C warming were thought to define the boundary of intol-
erable climate impacts, then the simplified DICE framework
under the median assumption of a 3
C climate sensitivity
would require a climate policy that restricted greenhouse gas
concentrations to roughly 550 parts per million (in carbon
dioxide equivalents). Adhering to a policy targeted at this
concentration limit would, however, fall well short of guar-
anteeing that the 3
C threshold would not be breached. As
shown in the first row of Table 24.6, in fact, focusing climate
policy on a concentration target of 550 ppm would produce
only a distribution of temperature change across the full range
of climate sensitivities with nearly 40% of the probability
anchored above 3
C. The associated discounted economic
Table 24.3 Exploring the economic value of deterministic interventions in the modified DICE environment.
Mean returns in billions of 1995$ with the standard deviations in parentheses.
Policy
context 1.5
2.0
3.0
4.0
5.0
6.0
7.0
8.0
9.0
Economic
value
68.34
(36.33)
86.36
(53.97)
95.38
(92.13)
84.21
(115.3)
72.38
(129.5)
62.59
(139.2)
54.05
(146.0)
44.65
(153.2)
44.65
(153.2)
Table 24.4 Exploring the economic value of the mean climate policy contingent on climate sensitivity in the modified DICE environment.
Return in billions of 1995$ and maximum temperature change in
C.
Climate sensitivity 1.5
2.0
3.0
4.0
5.0
6.0
7.0
8.0
9.0
Mean Standard deviation
Economic value 0 52 125 164 186 200 209 215 219 96.62 81.94
Max 1T 2.71 3.46 4.69 5.62 6.32 6.85 7.25 7.57 7.83 4.55 1.76
Table 24.5 Exploring the economic value of the responsive climate policy contingent on climate sensitivity in the modified DICE environment.
Return in billions of 1995$ and maximum temperature change in
C.
Climate sensitivity 1.5
2.0
3.0
4.0
5.0
6.0
7.0
8.0
9.0
Mean Standard deviation
Economic value 25 58 126 177 212 236 256 271 281 117.82 90.11
Max 1T 2.80 3.53 4.67 5.53 6.18 6.67 7.03 7.32 7.57 4.53 1.64
Yohe300
Human-Induced Climate Change : An Interdisciplinary Assessment, edited by Michael E. Schlesinger, et al., Cambridge University Press, 2007. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/wesleyan/detail.action?docID=321450.
Created from wesleyan on 2018-04-02 12:02:47.
Copyright © 2007. Cambridge University Press. All rights reserved.
values of this policy intervention (given the DICE calibration
of damages) are recorded in the second row, and they are not
very attractive. Indeed, the concentration target policy would
produce a positive value only if the climate sensitivity turned
out to be 9
C and the expected value shows a cost of $1.807
trillion (with a standard deviation of more than $1.1 trillion).
Table 24.7 shows the comparable statistics for a responsive
strategy of the sort described above; it focuses on temperature
and not concentrations, so it operates closer to the impacts side
of the climate system. In this case, the policy is adjusted in
2035 to an assumed complete understa nding of the climate
sensitivity so that the temperature increase is held below the
3
C threshold (barely, in the case of a 9
C climate sensitiv-
ity). In this case, the reduced damages associated with
designing a policy tied more closely to impacts dominates the
cost side and reduces the expected economic cost of the hedge
to a more manageable $535 billion with a standard deviation
of nearly $600 billion. Moreover, we know from the first
section that beginning this sort of hedging strategy early not
only reduces the cost of adjustment in 2035, but also preserves
the possibility of meeting more restrictive temperature targets
should they become warranted and the climate sensitivity turn
out to be high.
Finally, Table 24.8 illustrates what would happen if it were
determined in 2035 that the 3
C temperature target was not
required so that adjustment to an optimal deterministic policy
would be best. Notice that hedging would, in this eventuality,
produce non-negative economic value regardless of which
climate sensitivity were discovered. Indeed, the mean eco-
nomic value (discounted to 2005) exceeds $100 billion. Even
though the v ariance around this estimate is high (caused in
large measure because the valu e of the early hedging would be
very large if a high climate sensitivity emerged), this is surely
an attractive option.
24.5 Concluding remarks
The numerical results reported in Sect ion 24.4 are surely
model dependent, and they ignore many other sources of
uncertainty that would have a bearing on setting near-term
policy. They are not, however, the point of this paper. The
point of this paper is that decisionmakers at a national level
are already comfortable with approaching their decisions from
a risk-management perspective. As a result, they should wel-
come climate policy to their arsenal of tools when they come
to recognize climate change and its potential for abrupt and
intolerable impacts as another source of stress and uncertainty
with which they must cope. In this context, the numbers are
important because they are evidence that currently available
methods can provide the information that they need. More-
over, they are also important because they provide evidence
from the climate arena to support the insight drawn from a
Table 24.6 Exploring the economic value of a concentration-targeted climate policy contingent on climate sensitivity in the modified DICE
environment.
Return in trillions of 1995$ and maximum temperature change in
C.
Climate sensitivity 1.5
2.0
3.0
4.0
5.0
6.0
7.0
8.0
9.0
Mean Standard deviation
Economic value 3.04 2.49 1.58 0.99 0.61 0.35 0.17 0.03 0.08 1.81 1.12
Max 1T 1.83 2.31 3.00 3.45 3.79 4.06 4.29 4.48 4.65 2.86 0.96
Table 24.7 Exploring the economic value of the responsive temperature-targeted climate policy contingent on climate sensitivity in the
modified DICE environment.
Return in trillions of 1995$ and maximum temperature change in
C.
Climate sensitivity 1.5
2.0
3.0
4.0
5.0
6.0
7.0
8.0
9.0
Mean Standard deviation
Economic value 0.01 0.81 1.58 1.03 0.56 0.25 0.02 0.13 0.24 0.54 0.60
Max 1T 2.87 3.00 3.00 3.00 3.00 3.00 3.00 3.00 3.00 2.96 0.06
Table 24.8 Exploring the economic value of the responsive optimization after a temperature-targeted hedge contingent on climate sensitivity in
the modified DICE environment.
Return in billions of 1995$.
Climate sensitivity 1.5
2.0
3.0
4.0
5.0
6.0
7.0
8.0
9.0
Mean Standard deviation
Economic value 0 35 114 165 205 249 270 296 311 106.15 106.19
Lessons for mitigation from US monetary policy 301
Human-Induced Climate Change : An Interdisciplinary Assessment, edited by Michael E. Schlesinger, et al., Cambridge University Press, 2007. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/wesleyan/detail.action?docID=321450.
Created from wesleyan on 2018-04-02 12:02:47.
Copyright © 2007. Cambridge University Press. All rights reserved.
manipulation of the Brainard framework (where uncertainty
about the effect of policy is recognized) that doing nothing in
the near term is as much of a policy decision as doing
something.
Acknowledgements
I gratefully acknowledge the contributions and comments offered by
participants at the 2004 Snowmass Workshop and two anonymous
referees; their insights have improved the paper enormously. I would
also like to highlight the extraordinary care in editing and the
insightful contributions to content provided by Francisco de la
Chesnaye; Paco’s efforts were “above and beyond”. Finally, the role
played by William Brainard, my dissertation adviser at Yale, in
supporting this and other work over the years cannot be over-
estimated although I expect that Bill will be surprised to see his
work on monetary policy cited in the climate literature. Remaining
errors, of course, stay at home with me.
References
Alley, R. B., Marotzke, J., Nordhaus, W. et al. (2002). Abrupt
Climate Change: Irreversible Surprises. Washington DC:
National Research Council.
Andronova, N. G. and Schlesinger, M. E. (2001). Objective estima-
tion of the probability density function for climate sensitivity.
Journal of Geophysical Research 106 (D190), 22 605–22 611.
Brainard, W. (1967). Uncertainty and the effectiveness of monetary
policy. American Economic Review 57, 411–424.
Greenspan, A. (2003). Opening remarks, Monetary Policy and
Uncertainty: Adapting to a Changing Economy. Federal Reserve
Bank of Kansas City, pp. 1–7.
Greenspan, A. (2004). Risk and uncertainty in monetary policy.
American Economic Review 94 , 33–40.
IPCC (2001). Climate Change 2001: Impacts, Adaptation and Vulner-
ability. Contribution of Working Group II to the Third Assessment
Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change,ed.
J. J. McCarthy, O. F. Canziani, N. A. Leary, D. J. Dokken and
K. S. White. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press .
Jones, P. D. and Moberg, A. (2003). Hemispheric and large-scale
surface air temperature variations: an extensive revision and an
update to 2001. Journal of Climate 16, 206–223.
Keller, K., Bolker, B. M. and Bradford, D. F. (2004). Uncertain
climate thresholds and optimal economic growth. Global
Environmental Change 48, 723–741.
Lempert, R. and Schlesinger, M. E. (2000). Robust strategies for
abating climate change an editorial essay. Climatic Change 45,
387–401.
Manne, A. S. (1995). A Summary of Poll Results: EMF 14 Subgroup
on Analysis for Decisions under Uncertainty. Stanford Uni-
versity.
Nordhaus, W. D. and Boyer, J. (2001). Warming the World:
Economic Models of Global Warming. Cambridge, MA: MIT
Press.
Nordhaus, W. D. and Popp, D. (1997). What is the value of scientific
knowledge? An application to global warming using the PRICE
model. Energy Journal 18, 1–45.
Reinhart, V. (2003). Making monetary policy in an uncertain world.
In Monetary Policy and Uncertainty: Adapting to a Changing
Economy. Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City.
Revkin, A. (2005). Official played down emissions’ links to global
warming. New York Times, June 8th.
Schlesinger, M. E., Yin, J. Yohe, G. et al. (2005). Assessing the risk
of a collapse of the Atlantic thermohaline circulation. In
Avoiding Dangerous Climate Change. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Schneider, S. (2003). Abrupt Non-linear Climate Change, Irreversi-
bility and Surprise. ENV/EPOC/GSP(2003)13. Paris: Organiza-
tion for Economic Cooperation and Development.
Smith, J. and Hitz, S. (2003). Estimating the Global Impact of
Climate Change. ENV/EPOC/GSP(2003)12. Paris: Organization
for Economic Cooperation and Development.
Tol, R. S. J. (1998). Short-term decisions under long-term uncertainty.
Energy Economics 20, 557–569.
Walsh, C. E. (2003). Implications of a changing economic structure
for the strategy of monetary policy. In Monetary Policy and
Uncertainty: Adapting to a Changing Economy. Federal Reserve
Bank of Kansas City.
Yohe, G. (1996). Exercises in hedging against extreme consequences
of global change and the expected value of information. Global
Environmental Change 6, 87–101.
Yohe, G., Andronova, N. and Schlesinger, M. E. (2004). To hedge or
not to hedge against an uncertain climate future. Science 306,
416–417.
Yohe302
Human-Induced Climate Change : An Interdisciplinary Assessment, edited by Michael E. Schlesinger, et al., Cambridge University Press, 2007. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/wesleyan/detail.action?docID=321450.
Created from wesleyan on 2018-04-02 12:02:47.
Copyright © 2007. Cambridge University Press. All rights reserved.
–8 –4 –2 –1 –.5 –.2 .2 .5 1 2 4 8
–8 –4 –2 –1 –.5 –.2 .2 .5 1 2 4 8
Ts(K) Exp BC–Cld–Abs –0.12
Ts(K) Exp BC–No–Cld–Abs –0.11
Figure 3.1 Model simulated annual surface temperature change (K) for year 2000 Year 1850 for simulations that account for BC
absorption in-cloud (top panel) and that do not account for BC (bottom panel).
Human-Induced Climate Change : An Interdisciplinary Assessment, edited by Michael E. Schlesinger, et al., Cambridge University Press, 2007. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/wesleyan/detail.action?docID=321450.
Created from wesleyan on 2018-04-02 12:02:47.
Copyright © 2007. Cambridge University Press. All rights reserved.
0 .5 1 2 4 6 8 10 12 20
Exp A Biomass
Exp A Fossil/Bio–fuel
1.72
1.11
Figure 3.2 Annual values of carbonaceous aerosol column burden distribution (mg/m
2
) from biomass (top panel and fossil- and biofuel
sources (bottom panel). Global mean values are on the right-hand side of the figure.
Human-Induced Climate Change : An Interdisciplinary Assessment, edited by Michael E. Schlesinger, et al., Cambridge University Press, 2007. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/wesleyan/detail.action?docID=321450.
Created from wesleyan on 2018-04-02 12:02:47.
Copyright © 2007. Cambridge University Press. All rights reserved.
90
45
0
–45
–90
90
45
0
45
–90
90
45
0
–45
–90
–180 –90 0 90 180
–180 –90 0 90 180
–180 –90 0 90 180
Exp A
Exp CC1
Exp CC2
3.08
2.99
2.75
0 0.2 0.5 1 1.5 2 3 5 7 10 12 25
a
Figure 3.3 Continued
Human-Induced Climate Change : An Interdisciplinary Assessment, edited by Michael E. Schlesinger, et al., Cambridge University Press, 2007. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/wesleyan/detail.action?docID=321450.
Created from wesleyan on 2018-04-02 12:02:47.
Copyright © 2007. Cambridge University Press. All rights reserved.
–4.4 –2 –1 –0.6 –0.4 –0.2 0.2 0.4 0.6 1 2 4.4
–180 –90 0 90 180
–90
–45
0
45
90
b
Exp CC1 – Exp A –0.08
Figure 3.3 June–July–August precipitation (mm/day) fields for the year 2000 from Exp A, Exp CC1 and Exp CC2 (a), and change in
precipitation between Exp CC1 and Exp A (b). Global mean values are indicated on the right-hand side.
No Plantation
Eucalyptus grandis
Populus nigra
Picea abies
Larix
Biofuel
Figure 6.2 Carbon-plantation tree types for the year 2100 in the IM-C experiment. Because of the extra surplus-NPP constraint on
C-plantations and bioclimatic limits, the total area of these is smaller than that of biomass plantations. The additional area of biomass
plantations in the IM-bio experiment is indicated in red. Land-cover changes for regions other than the northern hemisphere regions
selected for the sensitivity experiments in this paper are not shown here.
Human-Induced Climate Change : An Interdisciplinary Assessment, edited by Michael E. Schlesinger, et al., Cambridge University Press, 2007. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/wesleyan/detail.action?docID=321450.
Created from wesleyan on 2018-04-02 12:02:47.
Copyright © 2007. Cambridge University Press. All rights reserved.
–0.5 –0.4 –0.3 –0.2 –0.1 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5
°C
ANN
0.1
0.1
0.1
0.2
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.1
0.1
0.3
0.2
0.1
0.1
0.1
0.2
0.2
0.1
Figure 6.8 Difference in annual-mean surface-air temperature in 2071–2100 (
C) of carbon-plantation with respect to biomass-
plantation ensemble mean, including albedo effects. Contours are plotted for all model grid cells. Colored are the grid cells for which the
difference between the two ensemble means is significant above the 95% level (2-tailed t-test).
2000
2050
2100
2150
2200 2250 2300
2350
2400
Year
400
380
360
340
320
2500
2250
2000
1750
1500
1250
1000
750
750
700
650
600
550
500
450
400
N
2
O concentration (ppb)
CH
4
concentration (ppb)
CO
2
concentration (ppm)
No-policy baseline (P50)
Overshoot
WRE450
WRE550
(a)
(b)
(c)
Figure 7.1 (a) Revised WRE and a new overshoot concentration stabilization profile for CO
2
compared with the baseline (P50)
no-climate-policy scenario. (b) Methane concentrations based on cost-effective emissions reductions (Manne and Richels, 2001)
corresponding to the WRE450, WRE550, and overshoot profiles for CO
2
. The baseline (P50) no-climate-policy scenario result
is shown for comparison. (c) Nitrous oxide concentrations based on cost-effective emissions reductions (Manne and Richels, 2001)
corresponding to the WRE450, WRE550, and overshoot profiles for CO
2
. The baseline (P50) no-climate-policy scenario result is shown
for comparison.
Human-Induced Climate Change : An Interdisciplinary Assessment, edited by Michael E. Schlesinger, et al., Cambridge University Press, 2007. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/wesleyan/detail.action?docID=321450.
Created from wesleyan on 2018-04-02 12:02:47.
Copyright © 2007. Cambridge University Press. All rights reserved.
2000
2050
2100
2150
2200
2250
2300 2350
2400
YEAR
–0.05
0.00
0.05
0.10
0.15
0.20
0.25
0.30
Warming rate (°C/decade)
WRE450
WRE550
Overshoot
Figure 7.4 Rates of change of global-mean temperature (
C/decade) for the temperature projections shown in Figure 7.3a.
Human-Induced Climate Change : An Interdisciplinary Assessment, edited by Michael E. Schlesinger, et al., Cambridge University Press, 2007. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/wesleyan/detail.action?docID=321450.
Created from wesleyan on 2018-04-02 12:02:47.
Copyright © 2007. Cambridge University Press. All rights reserved.
over
no data
to –5.0
to –2.0
to –0.5
to –0.1
to 0.0
to 0.1
to 0.5
to 1.0
over
no data
to –5.0
to –2.0
to –0.5
to –0.1
to 0.0
to 0.1
to 0.5
to 1.0
PCM exp 2100
HAD3 exp 2100
Figure 9.8 Aggregate impacts (percent change in GDP) in 2100.
0.000000001
0.00000001
0.0000001
0.000001
0.00001
0.0001
.0010
0.01
0.1
1
Fraction of land area
2100
2075
2050
2025
2000
0.00000001
0.0000001
0.000001
0.00001
0.0001
0.001
0.01
0.1
1
10
100
1000
Percent of GDP
2100
2075
2050
2025
2000
a
b
Figure 10.3 Loss of dryland (fraction of total area in 2000; panel(a)) and its value (percentage of GDP; panel(b)) without protection. Countries
are ranked as to their values in 2100.
Human-Induced Climate Change : An Interdisciplinary Assessment, edited by Michael E. Schlesinger, et al., Cambridge University Press, 2007. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/wesleyan/detail.action?docID=321450.
Created from wesleyan on 2018-04-02 12:02:47.
Copyright © 2007. Cambridge University Press. All rights reserved.
0.01
0.1
1
10
100
Percent of area
2100
2075
2050
2025
0.00001
0.0001
0.001
0.01
0.1
1
10
Percent of area
2100
2075
2050
2025
ab
Figure 10.4 Loss of wetland (fraction of total area in 2000; panel(a)) and its value (percentage of GDP; panel(b)) without protection (left
panels). Countries are ranked as to their values in 2100.
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
0.6
0.7
0.8
0.9
1.0
Fraction of land protected
2100
2075
2050
2025
0.0000001
0.000001
0.00001
0.0001
0.001
0.01
0.1
1
Percent of GDP
2025
2050
2075
2100
ab
Figure 10.5 Protection level (fraction of coast protected; left panel) and the costs of protection (percent of GDP; right panel). Countries
are ranked as to their protection level.
Human-Induced Climate Change : An Interdisciplinary Assessment, edited by Michael E. Schlesinger, et al., Cambridge University Press, 2007. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/wesleyan/detail.action?docID=321450.
Created from wesleyan on 2018-04-02 12:02:47.
Copyright © 2007. Cambridge University Press. All rights reserved.
Global Agro Ecological Zones (GAEZ)
AEZ1: Tropical, Arid
AEZ2: Tropical, Dry semi arid
AEZ3: Tropical, Moist semi arid
AEZ4: Tropical, Sub humid
AEZ5: Tropical, Humid
AEZ6: Tropical, Humid >300 day LGP
AEZ1: Temperate, Arid
AEZ2: Temperate, Dry semi arid
AEZ3: Temperate, Moist semi arid
AEZ4: Temperate, Sub humid
AEZ5: Temperate, Humid
AEZ6: Temperate, Humid >300 day LGP
AEZ1: Boreal, Arid
AEZ2: Boreal, Dry semi arid
AEZ3: Boreal, Moist semi arid
AEZ4: Boreal, Sub humid
AEZ5: Boreal, Humid
AEZ6: Boreal, Humid >300 day LGP
Figure 21.2 The global distribution of global agro-ecological zones (AEZ) from this study, derived by overlaying a global data set of
length of growing periods (LGP) over a global map of climatic zones. LGPs in green shading are in tropical climatic zones, LGPs in yellow-
to-red shading lie in temperate zones, while LGPs in blue-to-purple lie in boreal zones. LGPs increase as we move from lighter to dark
shades.
Human-Induced Climate Change : An Interdisciplinary Assessment, edited by Michael E. Schlesinger, et al., Cambridge University Press, 2007. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/wesleyan/detail.action?docID=321450.
Created from wesleyan on 2018-04-02 12:02:47.
Copyright © 2007. Cambridge University Press. All rights reserved.
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
Harvested Area (million ha)
45
40
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
India China U.S.A. Russian Brazil
Federation
rice
wheat
pulses
millet
sorghum
rice
wheat
maize
soy
rape
soy
maize
wheat
cotton
sorghum
wheat
barley
rye
sunflowerseed
potatos
soy
maize
sugarcane
pulses
rice
Figure 21.5 The top five nations of the world, in terms of total harvested area, the top five crops and their harvested areas within each nation,
and the AEZs they are grown in. Tropical AEZs are shown in green, temperate in yellow-to-red, and boreal in blue-to-purple.
Atmospheric Chemistry
Ocean Carbon
Cycle
Energy
System
Climate
Ocean
Temperature
Sea level
Terrestrial
Carbon
Cycle
Crops &
Forestry
Hydrology
Unmanaged
Ecosystem
& Animals
Coastal
System
Agriculture,
Livestock &
Forestry
Atmospheric Composition
Climate and Sea Level
Human Activities
Ecosystems
Other Human
Systems
Figure 31.1 A schematic diagram of the major components of a climate-oriented integrated assessment model.
Human-Induced Climate Change : An Interdisciplinary Assessment, edited by Michael E. Schlesinger, et al., Cambridge University Press, 2007. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/wesleyan/detail.action?docID=321450.
Created from wesleyan on 2018-04-02 12:02:47.
Copyright © 2007. Cambridge University Press. All rights reserved.
Scenarios
Assumptions
Policy Environment
Model
Analysis
Consequences
Economy
Climate
Figure 31.2 A schematic diagram of the elements of an IA model-based policy process.
Human-Induced Climate Change : An Interdisciplinary Assessment, edited by Michael E. Schlesinger, et al., Cambridge University Press, 2007. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/wesleyan/detail.action?docID=321450.
Created from wesleyan on 2018-04-02 12:02:47.
Copyright © 2007. Cambridge University Press. All rights reserved.
Human-Induced Climate Change : An Interdisciplinary Assessment, edited by Michael E. Schlesinger, et al., Cambridge University Press, 2007. ProQuest Ebook Central,
http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/wesleyan/detail.action?docID=321450.
Created from wesleyan on 2018-04-02 12:02:47.
Copyright © 2007. Cambridge University Press. All rights reserved.