Can Zoning Reform Reduce Housing Costs? Evidence
from Rents in Auckland
Ryan Gree
naway-McGrevy and Yun So
M
arch 2024
Economic Policy Centre
WORKING PAPER NO. 016
Can Zoning Reform Reduce Housing Costs? Evidence
from Rents in Auckland
Ryan Greenaway-McGrevy
and Yun So
First version: May 2023 This version: March 2024
Abstract
Zoning reform is increasingly advocated to redress unaffordable housing, but there
are few real-world examples to demonstrate its efficacy. However, in 2016, Auckland,
New Zealand, upzoned approximately three-quarters of its residential land, precip-
itating a boom in housing construction. In this paper we investigate whether the
zoning reform reduced housing costs, adopting a synthetic control method to spec-
ify rental prices in Auckland under the counterfactual of no zoning change. Rental
prices are measured using a hedonic index that quality-adjusts prices based on observ-
able attributes of the rental properties. Six years on from the reform, the synthetic
control from our preferred empirical specification implies that rents would be approxi-
mately 28% higher under the counterfactual. This difference is statistically significant
at a five percent level under the conventional rank permutation method applied to
post-treatment root mean squared error. Our findings support the proposition that
large-scale zoning reform can enhance housing affordability.
This research was funded by the Royal Society of New Zealand under Marsden Fund Grant UOA2013.
A previous version of this paper available here used the geometric mean of rents to measure rental
costs.Disclaimer: The results in this paper are not official statistics. They have been created for re-
search purposes from the Integrated Data Infrastructure (IDI), managed by Statistics New Zealand. The
opinions, findings, recommendations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are those of the author(s), not
Statistics NZ, Ministry of Business, Innovation and Employment. Access to the anonymised data used in
this study was provided by Statistics NZ under the security and confidentiality provisions of the Statistics
Act 1975. Only people authorised by the Statistics Act 1975 are allowed to see data about a particular
person, household, business, or organisation, and the results in this paper have been confidentialised to
protect these groups from identification and to keep their data safe. Careful consideration has been given to
the privacy, security, and confidentiality issues associated with using administrative and survey data in the
IDI. Further details can be found in the Privacy impact assessment for the Integrated Data Infrastructure
available from www.stats.govt.nz. We would like to acknowledge the Public Policy Institute for providing
datalab access.
University of Auckland. Corresponding author. Postal address: The University of Auckland, Private
Bag 92019 Auckland 1142, New Zealand. Email: [email protected].
Economic Policy Centre, University of Auckland.
1
1 Introduction
Housing has become increasingly expensive in many parts of the world, precipitating an
affordability crisis (Wetzstein, 2017; Saiz, 2023). A large number of economists and urban
planners attribute unaffordable housing, at least in part, to restrictive zoning (Gyourko and
Molloy, 2015; Been, 2018; Hamilton, 2021). Zoning reform is consequently advocated to
reduce housing costs by relaxing regulatory restrictions on the supply of medium and high
density housing, such as plexes, rowhouses and apartments (Glaeser and Gyourko, 2003;
Freeman and Schuetz, 2017).
1
However, up until very recently, few cities have pursued
large-scale upzonings to enable affordability (Schill, 2005; Freeman and Schuetz, 2017),
meaning there is little empirical evidence to support the posited effects of zoning reform.
In particular, there is, as yet, no empirical evidence to support claims that large-scale
zoning reform can reduce the cost of housing.
However, in 2016 the city of Auckland, New Zealand, upzoned approximately three-
quarters of its residential land (Greenaway-McGrevy and Jones, 2023), precipitating a con-
struction boom in the city (Greenaway-McGrevy and Phillips, 2023; Greenaway-McGrevy,
2023a), and affording us six years of data to examine the impact of the reform on housing
costs. In this paper, we assess the impact of the reform on rental prices, adopting a synthetic
control approach to specify the counterfactual scenario to the policy change. The synthetic
control is constructed from a donor pool comprising other commuting zones (which we
refer to as “urban areas”) in New Zealand, and matched to a variety of observed housing
market outcomes, including dwellings per capita and the average proportion of household
income allocated to housing among renting households. Rental prices are measured using
a hedonic price index constructed from individual dwelling data on rents available between
2000 and 2022.
2
Differences between actual and synthetic rental price indexes measure the impact of the
reform. However, the magnitude of the estimated policy impact is somewhat sensitive to
model specification. Our baseline specification implies that rents are 26.1% lower by 2022,
or, equivalently, rents would be 35.4% percent higher in Auckland under the counterfactual
of no reform (since 0.354 = 0.261/(1 0.261)). One particular donor unit receives a
weight of over seventy percent in this specification. When this unit is omitted from the
donor set, the estimated decrease in rents falls to 21.6%, indicating that the findings from
the baseline model are highly dependent on the specific donor. To be conservative in
our assessment of policy effects, we select a model specification that omits this donor as
our preferred model. Thus, our preferred empirical specification implies that rents in 2022
1
“Plexes” refers to duplexes, triplexes, sixplexes, etc.
2
At the time of writing, data were available for the years 2000 through 2022. We anticipate updating
the paper once data for 2023 become available.
2
would be 27.6% percent higher had Auckland not implemented zoning reform in 2016 (since
0.276 = 0.216/(1 0.216))).
The finding that large-scale zoning reform can reduce housing costs is important. While
researchers and policymakers have advocated for large-scale zoning reform as a means to
increase supply and enhance affordability, studies that focus on localized (or “spot”) upzon-
ings typically show muted or no effects on housing supply and/or affordability (Freemark,
2020; Dong, 2021), casting doubt on the ability of zoning changes to meet intended ob-
jectives (Rodr´ıguez-Pose and Storper, 2020). Such studies are also misused by advocates
and policymakers opposed to zoning reform as evidence that large-scale reforms will fail
(Cheung et al., 2023). Recently, Stacy et al. (2023) examine over fifty upzonings in various
cities in the U.S., finding only small effects on housing construction and costs. Results
from the present synthetic control approach indicate that the zoning reform undertaken as
part of the Auckland Unitary Plan did enhance housing afford ability, when measured by
rents, suggesting that large-scale reforms have substantially different impacts to localized
upzonings. This should be unsurprising. Compared to large-scale upzoning, conferring
redevelopment rights to a limited number of locations reduces the number of development
opportunities, and consequently generates less housing supply and smaller effects on hous-
ing costs.
Rental price indexes are constructed using the Ministry of Housing and Urban Devel-
opment (MHUD) dataset on individual rental bonds, which reports the weekly rent on new
tenancies in the country. The dataset also includes information on the number of bed-
rooms, property type (house, apartment or flat), state or private ownership, and location
(by meshblock). From these data, we calculate imputed hedonic price indexes using new
tenancies within each commuting zone. The price indexes are therefore quality-adjusted
using the observable attributes of the tenancies, including the number of bedrooms, housing
type, and location.
We use rents, rather than house prices, to measure housing costs for two reasons. First,
rents are not directly affected by enhanced redevelopment rights from zoning reform. The
effects of upzoning on housing prices is mediated by the land endowment of affected prop-
erties. Land prices in desirable locations increase in value (Greenaway-McGrevy, 2023b),
reflecting the increased capacity of the land to hold additional floorspace and the right to
redevelop the property into capital intensive dwellings. Properties that are relatively land
intensive, such as detached single family dwellings on large lots, are likely to appreciate in
value. Greenaway-McGrevy et al. (2021) present evidence consistent with this reasoning
after the reforms in Auckland. Rents, on the other hand, are not affected by the enhanced
development rights, which accrue to the landowner. Second, rents potentially capture hous-
ing costs across a wider socioeconomic demographic, given that low income households are
3
more likely to be tenants.
To assess the statistical significance of estimated rent decreases, we apply the rank
permutation test to the post-intervention root mean square errors (RMSEs) when the
placebo interventions are applied to donor units. Auckland has the largest post-treatment
RMSE among all 49 units in the donor pool, indicating that the counterfactual does a poor
job of describing actual outcomes, as would be anticipated if the policy was effective. If one
were to assign the intervention at random, the probability of obtaining a ratio as large as
Auckland’s is at most 0.02 (= 1/50). However, applying the rank permutation test to the
ratio of post- to pre- intervention RMSEs (Abadie et al. 2010), Auckland ranks between
third and twelfth, depending on model specification.
The synthetic control method has been applied to evaluate policy in a variety of contexts
(see Abadie, 2021 for a comprehensive review). We take several steps to ensure that our
research design and implementation is robust to common pathologies. First, we use the
longest possible times series on outcomes prior to intervention in order to minimize bias in
the synthetic unit (Abadie et al., 2010). Our rental time series spans 2000, when data for
individual bond tenancies begin, to 2022, with the intervention occurring in 2016. Second,
we examine how robust our findings are to changes in modeling assumptions, including
changes in the viable units in the donor set. Although the magnitude of implied rent
decreases does vary somewhat between specifications, in all specifications the decreases
are substantial. Third, our findings are largely unchanged under conventional robustness
check exercises that are commonly adopted in the synthetic control literature, including
the “leave one out” robustness check (Abadie et al., 2010), whereby units from the donor
pool are iteratively removed from the sample while the procedure is repeated.
Nonetheless, there are inherent limitations to the synthetic control method. Donor
units will be affected by the policy intervention if increased housing supply in Auckland
affects inter-city migration of tenants. Note, however, that in-migration to Auckland due
to lower housing costs generates attenuation bias in estimates of the casual impact, since
it reduces housing demand in other cities. More problematic is a population decrease in
Auckland from 2020 onwards, widely attributed to COVID-19 and policy responses thereto.
Statistics New Zealand estimates that Auckland’s population decreased by 1.1% between
June 2020 and June 2022, before increasing by 2.4% between June 2022 and June 2023.
Although media attention at the time focused mainly on Auckland, the same population
estimates show that other cities experienced population decreases between 2020 and 2022,
including (but not limited to) Dunedin (1.79%), Wellington (0.14%) and Rotorua (0.4%).
Notably, these cities experienced significant appreciation in rents between 2020 and 2022,
despite population decreases. We address this problem in two ways. First, we end the
sample in 2020, when the estimates of Auckland’s population peak. Rents in Auckland are
4
17.3% less than those of the synthetic control at this point. Second, we include estimates of
population decrease between 2020 and 2022 in the set of matching variables, and drastically
reduce the set of matching variables to those that feasibly predict the exodus, so that the
population decrease variable plays a prominent role in constructing the synthetic control
for Auckland. Rents are 22.9% less than those of the synthetic control in this specification
a larger decrease than that obtained under our preferred specification.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. The following section provides
the institutional details of the policy and provides a general background on Auckland and
New Zealand. Section three describes the data. In section four presents the method and
results. We first present our baseline empirical specification, before exploring variations of
the baseline model. Section five concludes.
2 Institutional Background
Housing costs in New Zealand are among the most expensive in the developed world.
Among renters and owner-occupiers with a mortgage, the median proportion of disposable
income (i.e. after taxes and transfers) spent on housing costs was 22% in 2021, exceeded
only by Australia, Greece and France in the OECD.
3
Among renting households, the median
proportion is 28%. As of the 2018 census, over a third (35.5%) of households are tenants.
4
This figure is higher for Auckland, where more than two-fifths (40.6%) of households rent
as of 2018.
Auckland is the largest city in New Zealand, with a population of 1.57 million as of
2018 (source: New Zealand census). In March 2013, the city announced the first version
of the Auckland Unitary Plan (AUP), which introduced and applied a standardized set
of planning zones across the jurisdiction, including four new residential zones. Three of
these zones encourage various gradations of medium to high density housing. After several
rounds of reviews and consultation, the plan was made operative in November 2016. Ap-
proximately three-quarters of residential land was upzoned, in the sense that effective FAR
restrictions on housing development were relaxed (Greenaway-McGrevy and Jones, 2023).
For additional details on the implementation of the plan and the spatial distribution of
upzoning, see Greenaway-McGrevy and Jones (2023).
Although the plan was operationalized in 2016, an agreement between the Auckland
Council and the central government called the ’Auckland Housing Accord’ allowed devel-
3
See Figure 10 here: https://www.msd.govt.nz/documents/about-msd-and-our-work/
publications-resources/monitoring/household-income-report/2021/international-
comparisons-of-housing-affordability.docx. Data for Auckland is not available.
4
Source: 2018 census https://www.stats.govt.nz/tools/2018-census-place-summaries/
auckland-region#housing
5
Figure 1: New dwelling permits in Auckland by 2016 zoning reform, 2000 to 2022
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 2022
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
New dwelling permits (thousands)
Reform
Partial Reform
Non-Upzoned Residential, Business and Rural Areas
Upzoned Residential and Business Areas
Notes: New dwelling permits in areas that were upzoned and were not upzoned in 2016 under the AUP.
The first, “draft”, version of the AUP was announced in March 2013, while the “Proposed” AUP (PAUP)
was notified in September 2013. Partial zoning reform was implemented in early October 2013 under the
Auckland Housing Accord. Between October 2013 and November 2016, Special Housing Area (SpHA)
developments could build to the regulations of the PAUP in exchange for affordable housing provisions.
Full reform occurred in November 2016 when the final version of the AUP became operative. Source:
Greenaway-McGrevy (2023a).
opers to build to the rules of the ’Proposed’ Auckland Unitary Plan (PAUP), announced
in September 2013.
5
This was an inclusionary zoning program that required developers to
offer a 10% proportion of affordable housing in exchange for accelerated permitting process
and the ability to build to the more relaxed land use regulations under the PAUP.
6
The
program ended once the AUP was implemented.
Housing supply quickly responded once the AUP was operative in 2016. Figure 1 ex-
hibits new dwelling permits issued per year, decomposed into upzoned and non-upzoned
areas. Permits increased significantly year-on-year from 2016 onwards, after the AUP is
operative, with all of the new construction occurring in upzoned areas. There is some
limited evidence of divergence from 2013 onwards, reflecting policy “leakage” as some de-
velopers took advantage of the relaxed regulations under the PAUP (see Figure 11 in the
Appendix, which separately identifies PAUP-SpHA permits in the data). Nonetheless, we
use 2016 as the date of the policy intervention in the synthetic control exercise, since this
the date after which the divergence becomes most evident, and accords with the full reform
becoming operative.
Our outcome of interest – rents – are likely to have been impacted by several legislative
changes over the period of analysis. However, these changes affected rental housing across
5
See https://www.beehive.govt.nz/sites/default/files/Auckland_Housing_Accord.pdf
6
The “Housing Accords and Special Housing Areas Act 2013” (HASHAA). See https://www.
legislation.govt.nz/act/public/2013/0072/latest/DLM5369001.html
6
the whole country, and we have little reason to think these changes would have a dispro-
portionate effect on Auckland. The sixth Labour government (2017–2023) substantially
altered regulations governing tenancies and the taxation of housing investors. Beginning
in 2018, it introduced a series of bills to: protect and enhance renters’ rights, including the
prohibition of letting fees and bidding for tenancies; limit tenant liabilities; and restrict
rent price increases (to every twelve months) and cause to terminate tenancies.
7
Legis-
lation to enhance minimum health and safety standards was passed in July 2019.
8
Tax
treatment of property investment also changed. From April 1, 2019, landlords could no
longer offset property investment losses against other sources of income when calculating
their income tax liability (known as ‘ring-fencing’),
9
and their ability to claim mortgage
interest as an expense on the rental property was phased out from October 2021.
10
Our
sample period also spans recent demand-side policies intended to curb housing demand
to promote house price affordability, including severe restrictions on foreign ownership,
disincentives to investor speculation, and macroprudential banking restrictions.
11
These
changes affected houses in all urban areas of the country, but nonetheless underscore the
need for the informed selection of a counterfactual scenario for policy evaluation.
3 Data
Individual data on new tenancies are collected by the Ministry of Housing and Urban De-
velopment (MHUD) on a quarterly basis. The data are not public, but can be accessed
via Statistics New Zealand’s Integrated Data Infrastructure (IDI). In addition to the rental
price, the dataset contains information on the rental property, including the number of bed-
rooms, housing types (“Flats” and “Houses”), public or private ownership, and meshblock,
which are equivalent to census tracts in the U.S. and provide a measure of location. From
these data we construct hedonic imputation price indexes, using number of bedrooms,
and indicators apartment, flat, and location (specifically, statistical area 2 units, which
comprise meshblocks).
12
We use the “double” imputation method, whereby the hedonic
regression is used to estimate prices in both the period of transaction and the period prior
7
See https://www.legislation.govt.nz/act/public/2018/0044/latest/LMS24553.html,
https://www.legislation.govt.nz/act/public/2020/0059/latest/LMS294929.html and https:
//www.legislation.govt.nz/act/public/2019/0037/latest/DLM7247512.html
8
Known as the “Healthy Homes Standards”. See https://www.legislation.govt.nz/regulation/
public/2019/0088/latest/whole.html.
9
See https://www.legislation.govt.nz/act/public/2007/0097/486.0/LMS223653.html
10
See https://www.legislation.govt.nz/act/public/2007/0097/latest/LMS675468.html
11
Loan to value ratios on new residential mortgages were introduced in 2013; a capital gains tax based
on duration of ownership was introduced in 2015; and legislation preventing foreign ownership (excepting
Australia and Singapore) in 2018. See Greenaway-McGrevy and Phillips (2021) for additional details.
12
We use fixed effects at the larger statistical area 2 (SA2) level, rather than meshblocks, due to data
sparsity at higher geographic resolutions. SA2s contain 2,000 to 4,000 persons in urban areas.
7
to the transaction (Eurostat, 2013). Refer to the appendix for a detailed description of the
method.
13
We use hedonic imputation to measure rental price changes because dwellings are het-
erogenous and infrequently transacted. Hedonic methods are more appropriate for differen-
tiated products or services (Silver and Heravi, 2007) than common alternatives such as re-
peated transaction (matched model) methods. For instance, repeated transaction methods
are subject to the “new goods” problem (Pakes, 2003), which refers to distortions in price
measurement stemming from changes in the composition of differentiated products within
the broader product class over time. Price differentials between different products are not
used in the measurement of inflation, which becomes problematic when new products are
introduced and extant products are retired each period. The problem is particularly acute
in housing, as each dwelling is different and infrequently transacted. Repeated transaction
methods are also subject to the “lemon’s bias” when applied to housing, because measured
prices become biased towards more frequently transacted properties (Clapp and Giaccotto,
1992).
Among the different hedonic approaches, hedonic imputation offers greater flexibility
than the hedonic time dummy approach, as it allows the hedonic coefficients on product
or service attributes to change over time. Pakes (2003) advocates for the use of hedonic
imputation over time dummy methods “since hedonic coefficients vary across periods it
[the time dummy hedonic method] has no theoretical justification.” Hedonic imputation
methods are generally preferred by statistical agencies such as Eurostat when measuring
house prices (Eurostat, 2013, pp. 159).
14
We use Functional Urban Areas (FUAs) as the geographic units of analysis. FUAs
are delineated by Statistics New Zealand on the basis of commuting patterns, and are
analogous to commuting zones as defined by the OECD.
15
There are 53 FUAs in New
Zealand, including Auckland. Henceforth, we use “urban areas” (UAs) as shorthand for
FUAs.
Figure 2 exhibits the rental price indexes for Auckland and the other urban areas of
New Zealand. Indexes are normalized to one in 2016, the year in which the zoning reform
becomes operational. We include a population-weighted average of the other urban areas.
Over the decade prior to the reform, rents in Auckland are growing at a faster rate
13
A previous version of this paper available here used the geometric mean of rents to measure rental
costs. As discussed in that version, a drawback of using averages (as opposed to quality-adjusted price
indexes) is that systematic changes in the composition of the rental stock can manifest as price changes.
14
Statistics New Zealand produces rental price indexes for five regions using a time dummy hedonic
model that is fitted to individual rental bond data over an eight-year sample window (see Bentley, 2022).
Because the model includes individual dwelling fixed effects, rental price changes are inferred from repeated
tenancies within the sample window, and are therefore subject to the new goods problem and lemon’s bias.
15
See https://www.stats.govt.nz/assets/Methods/Functional-urban-areas-methodology-and-
classification.pdf
8
that in the rest of the country (the rental price index is higher than the Auckland index
between 2007 and 2014 or so). In the six years since the reform, rental price increases in
the other urban areas have far exceed those in Auckland. By 2022, the rental price index
in Auckland is 1.181, whereas the population-weighted price index is 1.513. Rental prices
in other urban areas (as measured by the population-weighted average) have increased by
33.2 percentage points relative to Auckland between 2016 and 2022. This is a substantial
divergence.
Figure 2 also presents the index for Auckland against other the “metropolitan” urban
areas of the North Island of New Zealand: Auckland, Hamilton, Tauranga and Wellington.
16
We select these three urban areas as they are large cities that are comparatively close to
Auckland. (This comparison is purely for expositional purposes: In the analysis to follow we
use the synthetic control method to select appropriate controls.) Prior to the reform, rental
prices in Auckland were growing at a faster rate than in Hamilton and Wellington, but at
a slower rate than Tauranga. After the reforms, rental prices in Auckland are growing at a
slower rate than all three cities. By 2022, the rental price indexes of Tauranga, Hamilton
and Wellington range between 1.396 to 1.434. Thus, between 2016 and 2022, rental prices
in the other metropolitan cities of the North Island increased by 21.5 to 24.3 percentage
points more than Auckland. In other words, the inflation rate in Auckland after the AUP
was approximately half of that of proximate metropolitan cities.
3.1 Matching Variables
As we demonstrate in more detail in the following section, the synthetic control method
selects comparable control units by matching outcomes prior to the policy intervention.
These can include the outcome of interest (in our application, rental price indexes) as
well as other related variables. Here we describe the additional matching variables, all of
which are housing market outcomes, determinants of outcomes, or exogenous constraints
on housing supply.
Population growth. This is the log difference of estimated population by FUA. Censuses
occur in 2001, 2006, 2013 in the pre-reform era.
Dwellings per capita. This is the number of occupied dwellings in the FUA divided by
the usually resident population in the FUA. Both figures are obtained from census data.
The measure is obtained for the pre-reform census years of 2001, 2006, and 2013.
16
Statistics NZ classifies urban areas as either “metropolitan”, “large”, “medium” or “small”.
9
Figure 2: Rental price indexes in urban areas, 2000–2022
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 2022
Year
0.4
0.6
0.8
1
1.2
1.4
1.6
1.8
2
2.2
2.4
Rent Price Index (2016 = 1)
Reform
Auckland
Population-Weighted Average of Other Urban Areas
Other Urban Areas
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 2022
Year
0.4
0.6
0.8
1
1.2
1.4
1.6
Rent Price Index (2016 = 1)
Reform
Auckland
Hamilton
Tauranga
Wellington
Notes: Rental price indexes for Auckland and other urban areas of New Zealand, 2000 to 2022. Population
weights based on 2018 census populations. Indexes normalized to one in 2016, the year of Auckland’s
reform.
10
Personal income. We obtain the average personal income (from all sources) for the
census years 2001, 2006 and 2013 by FUA from Statistics New Zealand.
Proportion of renting households. Proportion of renting households within the FUA
for the two census years prior to the intervention, 2006 and 2013, by FUA from Statistics
New Zealand. Data for earlier census years for the required geographic units is unavailable.
Share of housing costs for renting households. We include the average proportion
of household income spent of rental costs for renting households, for 2006 and 2013. Census
data obtained from Statistics New Zealand. Data for earlier census years for the required
geographic units is unavailable.
Developable land. We calculate the proportion of the area within 25 kilometers of the
center of the urban area that is land under a 10 degree slope. We take the location of the
local council office as the center. This measure is inspired by Saiz (2010), who uses land
under a 15% slope as an exogenous instrument for housing supply, as such land can be
easily developed.
4 Synthetic Control Method and Results
This section outlines the synthetic control method and applies it to our dataset.
4.1 Synthetic Control Method
We have time series data on an outcome of interest for N +1 units indexed by i = 1, ..., N+1,
where i = 1 corresponds to the unit receiving the policy intervention, and i = 2, ...., N + 1
indexes the “donor pool”, a collection of untreated units that are unaffected by the inter-
vention.
17
Observations on the outcome of interest span t = 1, ..., T , where the observations
prior to intervention span t = 1, ..., T
0
and T
0
< T 1.
y
i,t
denotes the observed outcome of interest for unit i in period t. A synthetic control
is defined as a weighted average of the units in the donor pool. Given a set of weights
w = (w
2
, ..., w
N+1
), the synthetic control estimator of y
N
1,t
is ˆy
N
1,t
=
P
N+1
i=2
w
i
y
i,t
. Let y
N
1,t
be
the (unobservable) outcome without intervention for the first unit, while y
I
1,t
is the outcome
under the intervention in period t > T
0
. The effect of the intervention is then y
I
1,t
ˆy
N
1,t
.
Abadie and Gardeazabal (2003) and Abadie et al. (2010) choose w so that the resulting
synthetic control best resembles a set of pre-intervention “predictors” for the treated unit.
17
This section borrows heavily from Greenaway-McGrevy (2023a).
11
For each i, there is a set of k observed predictors of y
i,t
contained in the vector X
i
=
(x
1,i
, ..., x
k,i
), which can include pre-intervention values of y
i,t
unaffected by the intervention.
The k × N matrix X
0
= [X
2
· · · X
N+1
] collects the values of the predictors for the N
untreated units. Abadie and Gardeazabal (2003) and Abadie et al. (2010) select weights
w
= (w
2
, ..., w
N+1
) that minimize
X
1
X
0
w
v
=
k
X
h=1
v
h
(x
h,1
w
2
x
h,2
... w
N+1
x
h,N+1
)
2
!
1/2
(1)
subject to the restrictions w
h
[0, 1] and
P
N+1
i=2
w
i
= 1, and where v = (v
1
, ..., v
k
) is a set
of non-negative constants. Following Abadie et al. (2010), we choose v to assign weights to
linear combinations of the variables in X
0
and X
1
that minimize the mean square error of
the synthetic control estimator in the pre-treatment period. Then, the estimated treatment
effect for the treated unit at time t = T
0
, . . . , T is ˆy
N
1,t
=
P
N+1
i=2
w
i
y
i,t
.
Weights w that minimize (1) can found using standard quadratic programming solvers.
To select v in the nested RMSE-minimization problem, we use Evolution Strategy with
Covariance Matrix Adaptation (CMA-ES), which is a stochastic optimization algorithm
for solving difficult optimization problems (Hansen, 2016). It is considered a state of the
art evolutionary optimizer (Li et al., 2020).
18
In our application, we include all pre-treatment realizations of the outcome variable,
rents, in the set of predictors. As discussed in Abadie et al. (2010) and Abadie (2021),
increasing the pre-intervention time period T
0
reduces the bias in the synthetic control. In
our baseline specification, we include rents between 2000 and 2016. As discussed above,
we also include dwellings per capita, the proportion of renting households, and average
proportion of household income spent on rent among the matching variables. See section
three above for a discussion of the rationale for including these variables.
The synthetic control requires that the predictors of the treated unit must lie within the
convex hull of the predictors of the donor pool. The convex hull assumption is necessary
for the treated unit’s predictors to be approximated by the donor pool’s. We normalize the
price indexes to be one in 2016, and then take logs. Auckland’s price index satisfies the
convex hull condition prior to treatment.
We employ a hierarchical restriction of the donor pool for each urban area based on
Statistics New Zealand categories. Urban areas (UAs) in New Zealand are categorized as
“metropolitan”, “large”, “medium” and “small”, depending on size. “Metropolitan” con-
sists of six cities; “large” consists of eleven; and “medium” a further fourteen. The remain-
18
We adapt the Matlab version of the Synth package provided by Jens Hainmueller (available from
https://web.stanford.edu/
~
jhain/synthpage.html) to incorporate CMA-ES minimization of nested
RMSE objective function, using the cmaes.m matlab code provided by Nikolaus Hansen (available from
http://cma.gforge.inria.fr/cmaes.m).
12
der are “small”. Metropolitan UAs have their donor pool restricted to other metropolitan
UAs and large UAs in order to encourage similarity between Auckland its potential donors.
Abadie (2021, p. 409) notes that restricting the donor pool to units with similar charac-
teristics to the treated unit helps minimize interpolation biases. For placebo tests, large
UAs have their donor pool restricted to metropolitan, large and medium UAs. Medium
and small UAs do not have their donor sets restricted.
We omit Christchurch from the donor pool due to the impact of the 2011 earthquake
on its housing stock and other housing outcomes. As noted by Abadie (2021) (p. 409),
potential donor units that are subject to large idiosyncratic shocks to the outcome variable
should be withheld from the donor set. We also omit Queenstown, where rents fell by
20.3% in a single year, between 2019 and 2020. This sudden decrease is almost certainly
due to the policy response to COVID-19, as the region is highly dependent on tourism
and foreign workers, many of whom are on temporary work visas. (In the 2018 census,
47.7% of the population was foreign-born, compared to 27.4% for the nation as a whole.)
We also omit Warkworth, as the commuting zone is part of the Auckland region and
thus was also affected by the same zoning reform. This leaves a total of 50 UAs in the
dataset. However, of Christchurch, Queenstown and Warkworth, only Christchurch is a
metropolitan or large urban area. Thus, the omission of Queenstown and Warkworth has
no impact on the estimated synthetic control for Auckland in our baseline model. Taking
into account these restrictions, Auckland’s donor pool incorporates the other metropolitan
UAs except Christchurch (Hamilton, Tauranga, Wellington, Dunedin), as well as eleven
other large UAs, including the nearby cities such as Whang¯arei and Rotorua.
We also consider non-hierarchical selection of the donor units, whereby the full set of
49 urban areas may be selected. These variations are presented in section 4.4.
4.2 Results
Table 1 exhibits the selected weights for the baseline specification. Rotorua, a large ur-
ban area 194 km from Auckland (as the crow flies) with a population of 74,000 receives
a significant weight of almost three-quarters. Tauranga receives a weight of 0.188. It is a
metropolitan area 150km south east of Auckland with an estimated population of 156,666.
Finally, Invercargill is another large urban area over 1000 km from Auckland with a pop-
ulation of 55,386. It receives a weight of 0.069.
Table 2 exhibits Auckland’s matching variables and those of synthetic Auckland. We
include the average of the donor pool for comparison. Personal income, the proportion of
rent households, and the proportion of income allocated to rent among renting households
are matched reasonably well. Dwellings per capita are lower in Auckland than its synthetic
counterpart. This may reflect regional differences in preferences over family sizes. Popu-
13
Table 1: Weights
Urban Area Weight Urban Area Weight
Hamilton 0 Napier 0
Tauranga 0.188 Hastings 0
Wellington 0 Whanganui 0
Dunedin 0 Palmerston North 0
Whang¯arei 0 apiti Coast 0
Rotorua 0.743 Nelson 0
Gisborne 0 Invercargill 0.069
New Plymouth 0
Figure 3: Synthetic and actual rental price indexes
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 2022
Year
-0.8
-0.6
-0.4
-0.2
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
Log Rent Price Index
Actual Auckland
Synthetic Auckland
lation growth is also very poorly matched. Finally, the proportion of developable land is
much larger in synthetic Auckland. Because the inner loop of the synthetic control method
minimizes RMSE prior to the intervention, these results imply dwellings per capita, popu-
lation growth, and the proportion of developable land are not useful in explaining variation
in rental price changes prior to the reform.
Figure 3 depicts actual and synthetic rental price indexes for Auckland. There is a no-
table divergence from 2016 onwards, with prices growing much more slowly than synthetic
prices. By 2022, log rents in Auckland are 0.303 less than the synthetic control, corre-
sponding to a 26.1 percent (= 1 e
0.303
) decrease in rents relative to the counterfactual
of no zoning reform. Equivalently, rents in 2022 would be between 35.4% percent higher
had Auckland not implemented the reform.
However, we show in section 4.4.1 that the estimated reduction in rents due to the
reform falls to 21.6% when Rotorua is omitted from the donor set. The results are therefore
somewhat sensitive to inclusion of Rotorua.
14
Table 2: Matched variables
Variable Auckland Synthetic Auckland Average of Donors
Dwellings per capita, 2013 0.332 0.387 0.389
Dwellings per capita, 2006 0.338 0.378 0.385
Dwellings per capita, 2001 0.343 0.374 0.384
Population growth, 2006 to 2013 0.125 0.039 0.067
Population growth, 2001 to 2006 0.091 0.029 0.031
Proportion of developable land 0.453 0.554 0.372
Personal income ($), 2013 30,200 27,080.26 27,744.24
Personal income ($), 2006 27,200 23,621.96 23,417.84
Personal income ($), 2001 21,500 17,993.57 17,595.20
Proportion of households renting, 2013 0.388 0.365 0.336
Proportion household renting, 2006 0.363 0.336 0.317
Proportion of income spent on rent, 2013 0.262 0.245 0.250
Proportion of income spent on rent, 2006 0.244 0.224 0.229
Notes: Matching variables also include rent indexes, 2000 to 2016, but these are not tabulated for the sake
of brevity. Population growth is log difference of estimated population. Proportion of income spent on
rent is based on pre-tax income for renting households.
4.3 Inference
We run placebo interventions on the other donor units to assess whether the decrease
relative to the counterfactual is large. Figure 4 plots the difference between the actual
outcomes of each donor and its synthetic control. Evidently the decrease in Auckland’s
prediction error is the largest (in magnitude) among all units over the post-intervention
period, indicating that the zoning reform had a substantive negative impact.
To conduct statistical inference we apply the rank permutation approach to the root
mean square prediction errors (RMSEs) between the actual and synthetic units in the
post-intervention period. Define the RMSE for unit i over t = t
1
to t = t
2
as
R
i
(t
1
, t
2
) =
v
u
u
t
1
t
2
t
1
t
2
X
t=t
1
Y
i,t
ˆ
Y
N
i,t
2
R
i
(T
0
+ 1, T) is therefore the post-treatment RMSE for unit i. The post-treatment RMSE
is constructed for Auckland and all placebo runs. (These is sometimes referred to as “in
space placebos”.) The rank permutation test is then based on where the RMSE for the
treated unit ranks among all placebo runs. For example, if the ratio was ranked second
among all 50 runs, then if one were to assign the intervention at random, the probability
of obtaining a ratio that is second largest is 0.04 ( = 2/50).
15
Figure 4: Prediction errors
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 2022
Year
-0.5
-0.4
-0.3
-0.2
-0.1
0
0.1
0.2
0.3
Notes: Prediction errors are the difference between actual and synthetic outcomes for Auckland (black)
and placebo runs (gray).
Figure 5 depicts the histogram of the ratios. Auckland has the largest RMSE, meaning
that the probability of obtaining a ratio that is largest is 0.02 ( = 1/50).
Abadie et al. (2010) also suggests using the ratio of pre- to post- intervention RMSE as
a basis for inference, namely
r
i
=
R
i
(T
0
+ 1, T)
R
i
(1, T
0
)
The ratio is constructed for the treated unit and all placebo runs, and the rank permutation
test is then based on where the ratio for the treated unit ranks among all placebo runs.
However, one drawback of the ratio is that it does not distinguish between positive and
negative deviations from the synthetic unit, whereas many hypotheses posit a directional
change from an intervention. For example, the relevant alternative hypothesis in our case is
that zoning reform reduced housing costs. Substantial increases in power can be obtained
by testing for reductions relative to the synthetic control, rather than absolute differences
(Abadie, 2021). To conduct a one-tailed test, we compute
r
i
=
R
i
(T
0
+ 1, T)
R
i
(1, T
0
)
where
R
i
(t
1
, t
2
) =
v
u
u
t
1
t
2
t
1
t
2
X
t=t
1
j
Y
i,t
ˆ
Y
N
i,t
k
2
where x = 0 iff x > 0 and x = x otherwise. We refer to this as the “Negative Error
16
Figure 5: Post-treatment root mean square errors
Notes: Auckland appears in black.
Figure 6: Negative-error RMSE ratios
Notes: Auckland appears in black.
RMSE Ratio”, or NE-RMSE-R.
19
Figure 6 depicts the histogram of the ratios. Auckland is ranked ninth out of fifty,
outside conventional levels of statistical significance. While its post-intervention RMSE
is second largest, Auckland’s pre-intervention RMSE is also somewhat large, causing the
NE-RMSE-R to be ranked somewhat lower that the post intervention RMSE.
19
Because the final pre-intervention observations are normalized to zero, the pre-intervention RMSE
omits the intervention year.
17
Figure 7: Leave-one-out robustness check
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 2022
-0.8
-0.6
-0.4
-0.2
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
Notes: Leave-one-out replications in gray. The synthetic control for the full sample is the red dashed line.
4.4 Robustness Checks
4.4.1 Leave-One-Out
We perform the “leave one out” robustness check (Abadie et al., 2010), whereby units from
the donor pool are iteratively removed from the sample while the procedure is repeated.
This procedure examines the extent to which the synthetic control may be dependent on
any single given donor unit.
Figure 7 exhibits the full-sample synthetic control (FS-SC, given by the red dashed line)
alongside leave-one-out synthetic controls (LOO-SCs, given by the gray lines). In general,
each of the LOO-SCs follow a common trend over both the pre- and post- sample period.
This indicates that the results are not particularly sensitive to any one urban area being
included in the donor set.
There is, however, one clear case in Figure 7 where synthetic rents are slightly lower
over the post-treatment period. This corresponds to when Rotorua, which receives a weight
of almost three quarters, is omitted from the donor set.
Given that results are somewhat sensitive to the inclusion of Rotorua in the donor
set, we single out the case where Rotorua is left out. Under this specification, Tauranga
receives a weight of 0.575, while Palmerston North receives 0.424. The latter is a large
urban area of approximately 100,000 residents, 400km south of Auckland. Table 4 in
the Appendix exhibits the matching variables, showing that population growth is now
much better matched by the synthetic unit, while the match to the proportion of renting
households is slightly worse.
The top panel of Figure 8 depicts actual and synthetic rental price indexes. The syn-
thetic control implies a 0.243 reduction in log rents, corresponding to 21.6% decrease.
18
Equivalently, rents would be 27.6% higher under the counterfactual of no reform (since
0.276 = 0.216/(1 0.216)). Auckland’s post intervention RMSE still ranks first among
placebos, indicating that the smaller reduction is nonetheless statistically significant when
evaluated by this measure. It’s NE-RMSE-R ranks twelfth.
As discussed in the introduction, we select this as our preferred specification. The
inclusion of a single unit Rotorua in the donor set has a substantial effect on estimated
policy impacts. Once it is removed from the donor set, the policy impact is somewhat
smaller in magnitude. To be conservative in our assessment, we headline these results as
our preferred empirical specification.
4.4.2 Unrestricted Selection of Donor Units
In our baseline set of models, donor units for Auckland and “metropolitan” and “large”
urban areas are restricted. In this subsection we present results when these restrictions are
not imposed, such that donor units for Auckland comprise the other 49 urban areas in the
sample.
Rotorua, Gore and anaka receive weights of 0.678, 0.204, and 0.118. Thus, the large
weight on Rotorua is similar to the baseline specification presented in section 4.2, while
Gore and anaka replace Invercargill and Tauranga. anaka is a small urban area 990
km south from Auckland (as the crow flies) with a population of 15,000, while Gore in
a small urban area 1150 km south of Auckland with an estimated population of 12,500.
The middle panel of Figure 8 exhibits synthetic and actual rental indexes. By 2022, log
rents in Auckland are 0.310 less than the synthetic control, corresponding to a 26.7 percent
(= 1 e
0.310
) decrease in rents relative to the counterfactual of no zoning reform. Thus,
under non-hierarchical selection, the decrease in rents due to the reform is estimated to
be even larger. Auckland has the second largest post-treatment RMSE. The probability
of obtaining the largest RMSE is 0.041 ( = 2/49). Meanwhile, Auckland’s NE-RMSE-R
ranks tenth
4.4.3 Population Decreases after COVID-19
According to Statistics New Zealand estimates, Auckland’s population decreased by 1.07%
between 2020 and 2022.
20
The ability of the synthetic control to account for the effect of
a population decrease on rents in Auckland depends on whether the matching variables
20
Population estimates are as at June. For information on methodology, see https://datainfoplus.
stats.govt.nz/item/nz.govt.stats/951e3175-d94d-4d67-9af7-47c0a75f90d9/7. As of May 2023,
the subnational population estimates at 30 June 2021 and 2022 are both provisional. Estimates for the
year to June 2023 were released on 25 October, showing that there was a 2.8% increase in the Auckland
Region’s population over this period. This gain is more than sufficient to reverse the loss in population
over the previous two years.
19
Figure 8: Synthetic and actual rental price indexes, robustness checks
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 2022
Year
-0.8
-0.6
-0.4
-0.2
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
Log Rent Price Index
Actual Auckland
Synthetic Auckland
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 2022
Year
-0.8
-0.6
-0.4
-0.2
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
Log Rent Price Index
Actual Auckland
Synthetic Auckland
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 2022
Year
-0.8
-0.6
-0.4
-0.2
0
0.2
0.4
0.6
Log Rent Price Index
Actual Auckland
Synthetic Auckland
Notes: Top: Donor with the largest weight (Rotorua) omitted from the donor set. Middle: Unrestricted
selection of donors, including medium and small urban areas. Bottom: Matching to urban areas with
population decreases between 2020 and 2022.
20
Figure 9: Rental prices for urban areas with population decreases between 2020 and 2022
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 2022
Year
0.4
0.6
0.8
1
1.2
1.4
1.6
1.8
Rent Price Index (2016 = 1)
Reform
Auckland
Wellington
Dunedin
Rotorua
Invercargill
Notes: Rental price indexes for urban areas that experienced a decrease in estimated population between
2020 and 2022.
select control units that experienced similar decreases. In this regard, Auckland was not
unique among urban areas in experiencing a decline. Among the metropolitan and large
urban centers, Wellington (-0.16%), Dunedin (-1.83%), Rotorua (-0.55%), Invercargill (-
0.53%) also experienced decreases in (estimated) population. Notably, some of these urban
areas already feature in the selected donor pool for Auckland, suggesting that the set
of predictors may span the set of variables that explain the population decline. Figure
9 depicts rents of urban areas that experienced population decreases between 2020 and
2022. All except Auckland exhibit substantial appreciation from 2016 onwards, including
Dunedin, which is notable for being the urban area that experienced a larger population
exodus than Auckland. Thus, despite having a larger population exodus than Auckland,
Dunedin experienced a substantially larger increase in rents.
Although Auckland was not the only urban area to experience a population decrease, the
incidence and responses to COVID-19 may present a unique shock that disproportionately
affected Auckland and that proves difficult for the synthetic control to adequately model
from 2020 onwards.
We modify our empirical strategy in two different ways to address this potential problem.
First, we end the sample in 2020, when estimated population in Auckland peaks. Second, we
re-specify the set of matching variables to comprise the decrease in population from 2020
to 2022, and a limited number of rental market characteristics. This tilts the synthetic
control procedure towards selecting urban areas that experienced a decrease in population
from 2020 onwards.
21
Ending the sample in 2020. By 2020, log rents in Auckland are 0.192 less than the
synthetic control, corresponding to a 17.3 percent (= 1 e
0.190
) decrease in rents relative
to the counterfactual of no zoning reform. Auckland has the largest post-intervention
RMSE, meaning that the probability of obtaining a RMSE that is largest is 0.02 ( = 1/50).
Auckland’s NE-RMSE-R ranks eighth.
Matching post 2020 population decreases. We set the matching variables to include
the log population change between 2020 and 2022. We also include the proportion of people
aged 18 to 22 inclusive, to account for the potential effect of the border closure and interna-
tional students returning home, in 2013. Both Auckland and Dunedin, which experienced
the largest population decreases, have a large tertiary sector that serves international as
well as domestic students. We also restrict the donor pool to urban areas that experienced
a population decrease between 2020 and 2022.
Motueka, Dunedin, Rotorua, Gore, Invercargill, Dannevirke and Wellington receive
weights of 0.319, 0.267, 0.0947, 0.0946, 0.0913, 0.071 and 0.062. The model is able to
match population decrease exactly due to the few number of matching variables. The
bottom panel of Figure 8 exhibits synthetic and actual rents. Pre-intervention fit of the
synthetic unit is noticeably impaired when compared to the baseline model. By 2022, log
rents in Auckland are 0.261 less than the synthetic control. This is a smaller decrease
than under the baseline model, but nonetheless implies a 22.9% (= 1 e
0.261
) reduction
in rents. Auckland has the eighth largest post-intervention RMSE, and the third largest
NE-RMSE-R. The probability of obtaining a ratio that is third largest is 0.06 ( = 3/50).
5 Concluding Remarks
In 2016, Auckland implemented a large-scale zoning reform that precipitated a boom in
housing construction. In this paper we adopt a synthetic control approach to evaluate the
impact of the reform on rents. Across different specifications, the synthetic control method
indicates that, six years on, rents in Auckland would be at least 27% higher had Auckland
not pursued this reform.
The effects of large-scale upzoning posited by advocates of reform should no longer be
considered to be purely theoretical. Auckland’s experience suggests that zoning reform
can stimulate housing supply and reduce housing costs. Policymakers seeking to redress
persistent housing shortages and unaffordability should consequently consider reforming
residential zoning codes to allow cities to build medium and high density housing.
Our findings for Auckland are, however, a medium-run evaluation of the reform, given
the six-year horizon of the study. Long-run effects may depend on inter-regional migration
22
in response to lower housing costs, with in-migrants potentially eroding away reductions
in rents, and underscoring the need for coordinated or concurrent action across different
cities. New Zealand’s recently-elected center-right government has pledged to repeal similar
reforms that it recently helped pass to enable medium density housing in New Zealand’s
largest cities.
21
Repealing this legislation will potentially increase in-migration pressures
into Auckland in response to its earlier, unilateral, reform, potentially reducing the effect
of the reform on housing affordability over the long term if other large cities do not (or are
not incentivised to) follow Auckland’s lead and reform their zoning codes to allow more
housing development.
We conclude by noting that housing costs in Auckland remain among the most ex-
pensive in the world, as measured by either the proportion of disposable income spent on
housing or house prices relative to incomes. This observation is not, however, evidence
against the efficacy of Auckland’s reform, since it leaves the counterfactual unspecified.
The evidence presented herein indicates that housing costs would have been even more
expensive had Auckland not reformed its zoning code. Nonetheless, our findings do sug-
gest that Auckland’s reform is not a panacea, and that additional policy tools and further
reforms may be necessary to bring housing costs down to affordable levels.
21
In December 2021, the center-left Labour and center-right National parties voted to pass the Medium
Density Residential Standard (MDRS), which requires the five largest cities in New Zealand to employ a
medium density default of three storeys and three dwellings per parcel in residential areas. To date, only
two councils (Hutt City and Upper Hutt) have operationalized the MDRS.
23
6 Appendix
6.1 Hedonic Imputation Index
Our sample of rental bonds consists of apartments, houses and flats. Bonds with no record
of the dwelling type are omitted. We restrict the sample to private dwellings, as many
public rentals are subsidized, and this is the convention followed by Statistics New Zealand
when constructing rental price indexes. Let p
i(t),t
denote the logged weekly rent of house
i (t) sold in period t, and let X
i(t),t
be a vector of characteristics. The hedonic regression is
p
i(t),t
= X
i(t),t
β
t
+ ε
i(t),t
, (2)
where t = 1, ..., T indexes time periods (years), and i(t) = 1(t), ..., n(t) indexes the cross
sections observed in period t. We include the following observable characteristics in X
i(t),t
:
number of bedrooms, a dummy for apartment, a dummy for flat, and locational dummies
(specifically, SA2 dummies). The vector of characteristics X
i(t),t
also includes a constant.
For each FUA, we fit (2) to the cross section of rents for t = 1, ..., T , obtaining
n
ˆ
β
t
o
T
t=1
. For each observation i(t) in period t, we use the estimated hedonic function to impute
rents in period t as ˆp
i(t),t
= X
i(t),t
ˆ
β
t
, and t 1 as ˆp
i(t),t1
= X
i(t),t
ˆ
β
t1
. We then run the
following regression
ˆp
i(t),t
ˆp
i(t),t1
= δ
t
+ u
i(t),t
, t = 2, ..., T
The sequence
n
e
ˆ
δ
t
o
T
t=1
yields the hedonic imputation price index, where
ˆ
δ
1
= 0.
6.2 Additional Tables and Figures
24
Figure 10: Metropolitan and large urban areas of New Zealand
Figure 11: New dwelling permits in Auckland by 2016 zoning change, 2000 to 2022
2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 2018 2020 2022
0
2
4
6
8
10
12
14
16
18
20
New dwelling permits (thousands)
Reform
Partial Reform
Non-Upzoned Residential, Business and Rural Areas
Upzoned Residential and Business Areas
PAUP-SpHA in Non-Upzoned Areas
PAUP-SpHA in Upzoned Areas
Notes: New dwelling permits in areas that were and were not upzoned in 2016 under the AUP, with permits
issued under to Special Housing Areas (SpHA) separately identified. See notes to Figure 1 for additional
details.
25
Table 3: Functional urban area statistics
Urban Area Population Dwellings Pers. Inc. ($) Area (km
2
) Prop. dev. land Dist. Auck. (km)
Auckland 1,567,038 490,695 36,000 3356.9 0.4532 -
Hamilton 209,970 70,596 33,700 1412.7 0.8217 114
Tauranga 156,666 57,690 33,300 789.9 0.3942 155
Wellington 422,427 149,820 39,700 1754.2 0.1212 493
Christchurch 482,088 177,135 35,400 2408.0 0.5797 764
Dunedin 132,006 49,533 27,400 1033.8 0.2278 1,064
Whang¯arei 86,538 31,407 29,000 1433.6 0.5402 131
Rotorua 74,028 24,795 29,100 649.2 0.5902 194
Gisborne 43,953 15,360 28,000 612.8 0.2432 350
Hastings 79,431 26,823 29,700 1160.4 0.5142 359
Napier 66,459 24,834 30,400 259.8 0.3496 348
New Plymouth 80,997 31,002 31,800 920.9 0.3967 253
Whanganui 45,747 18,249 25,400 598.1 0.3374 344
Palmerston North 96,552 34,737 32,000 978.3 0.7821 397
apiti Coast 46,839 19,128 32,100 317.4 0.1705 452
Nelson 84,846 31,833 31,300 1177.2 0.1855 508
Invercargill 55,386 21,825 31,700 428.5 0.7148 1,188
Source: Authors’ calculations based on 2018 census. Notes: Only metropolitan and large urban areas are
tabulated. Dwellings are occupied dwellings. Note that Christchurch is omitted from Auckland’s donor
pool due to the effect of the 2011 earthquakes on the housing stock and subsequent rebuild.
Table 4: Matched variables, Rotorua omitted from donors
Variable Auckland Synthetic Auckland Average of Donors
Dwellings per capita, 2013 0.332 0.389 0.389
Dwellings per capita, 2006 0.338 0.387 0.386
Dwellings per capita, 2001 0.343 0.386 0.385
Population growth, 2006 to 2013 0.125 0.115 0.071
Population growth, 2001 to 2006 0.091 0.084 0.033
Proportion of developable land 0.453 0.527 0.361
Personal income ($), 2013 30,200 27,926.99 27,808.35
Personal income ($), 2006 27,200 23,742.41 23,399.14
Personal income ($), 2001 21,500 17,552.28 17,549.18
Proportion of households renting, 2013 0.388 0.347 0.333
Proportion of household renting, 2006 0.363 0.332 0.314
Proportion of income spent on rent, 2013 0.262 0.252 0.251
Proportion of income spent on rent, 2006 0.244 0.227 0.229
Notes: Matching variables also include rent indexes, 2000 to 2016. These are not tabulated for the sake of
brevity. Population growth is log difference of estimated population. Proportion of income spent on rent
is based on pre-tax income for renting households.
26
References
Abadie, A. (2021): “Using Synthetic Controls: Feasibility, Data Requirements, and
Methodological Aspects,” Journal of Economic Literature, 59. 4, 12, 13, 16
Abadie, A., A. Diamond, and J. Hainmueller (2010): “Synthetic control methods for
comparative case studies: Estimating the effect of California’s Tobacco control program,”
Journal of the American Statistical Association, 105, 493–505. 4, 11, 12, 16, 18
Abadie, A. and J. Gardeazabal (2003): “American Economic Association The Eco-
nomic Costs of Conflict: A Case Study of the Basque Country,” The American Economic
Review, 93, 113–132. 11, 12
Been, V. (2018): “City NIMBYs,” Journal of Land Use and Environmental Law, 33,
217–250. 2
Bentley, A. (2022): “Rentals for Housing: A Property Fixed-Effects Estimator of Infla-
tion from Administrative Data,” Journal of Official Statistics, 38, 187–211. 8
Cheung, K. S., P. Monkkonen, and C. Y. Yiu (2023): “The heterogeneous impacts
of widespread upzoning: Lessons from Auckland, New Zealand,” Urban Studies. 3
Clapp, J. M. and C. Giaccotto (1992): “Estimating price indices for residential
property: A comparison of repeat sales and assessed value methods,” Journal of the
American Statistical Association, 87, 300–306. 8
Dong, H. (2021): “Exploring the Impacts of Zoning and Upzoning on Housing Develop-
ment: A Quasi-experimental Analysis at the Parcel Level,” Journal of Planning Educa-
tion and Research, 00, 1–13. 3
Eurostat (2013): Handbook on Residential Property Prices (RPPIs). 8
Freeman, L. and J. Schuetz (2017): “Producing Affordable Housing in Rising Markets:
What Works?” Cityscape, 19. 2
Freemark, Y. (2020): “Upzoning Chicago: Impacts of a Zoning Reform on Property
Values and Housing Construction,” Urban Affairs Review, 56, 758–789. 3
Glaeser, E. L. and J. Gyourko (2003): “Building restrictions and housing availabil-
ity,” Economic Policy Review, 21–39. 2
Greenaway-McGrevy, R. (2023a): “Can Zoning Reform Increase Housing Construc-
tion? Evidence from Auckland,” Economic Policy Centre Working Paper 017. 2, 6,
11
27
——— (2023b): “Evaluating the Long-Run Effects of Zoning Reform on Urban Develop-
ment,” Economic Policy Center Working Paper 013. 3
Greenaway-McGrevy, R. and J. A. Jones (2023): “Can zoning reform change urban
development patterns? Evidence from Auckland,” Economic Policy Centre Working
Paper 012. 2, 5
Greenaway-McGrevy, R., G. Pacheco, and K. Sorensen (2021): “The effect of
upzoning on house prices and redevelopment premiums in Auckland, New Zealand,”
Urban Studies, 58, 959–976. 3
Greenaway-McGrevy, R. and P. Phillips (2023): “The Impact of Upzoning on
Housing Construction in Auckland,” The Jounral of Urban Economics, 136, 103555. 2
Greenaway-McGrevy, R. and P. C. B. Phillips (2021): “House prices and afford-
ability,” New Zealand Economic Papers, 55, 1–6. 7
Gyourko, J. and R. Molloy (2015): “Regulation and Housing Supply,” Handbook of
Regional and Urban Economics, 5, 1289–1337. 2
Hamilton, E. (2021): “Land Use Regulation and Housing Affordability,” in Regulation
and Economic Opportunity, ed. by A. Hoffer and T. Nesbit, Center for Growth and
Opportunity at Utah State University, 186–202. 2
Hansen, N. (2016): “The CMA Evolution Strategy: A Tutorial,” arXiv preprint
arXiv:1604.00772. 12
Li, Z., X. Lin, Q. Zhang, and H. Liu (2020): “Evolution strategies for continuous
optimization: A survey of the state-of-the-art,” Swarm and Evolutionary Computation,
56. 12
Pakes, A. (2003): “A Reconsideration of Hedonic Price Indexes with an Application to
PC’s,” American Economic Revieweview, 93, 1578–1596. 8
Rodr
´
ıguez-Pose, A. and M. Storper (2020): “Housing, urban growth and inequali-
ties: The limits to deregulation and upzoning in reducing economic and spatial inequal-
ity,” Urban Studies, 57, 223–248. 3
Saiz, A. (2010): “The Geographic Determinants of Housing Supply,” The Quarterly Jour-
nal of Economics, 125, 1253–1297. 11
——— (2023): “The Global Housing Affordability Crisis: Policy Options and Strategies,”
MIT Center for Real Estate Research Paper No. 23/01. 2
28
Schill, M. H. (2005): “Regulations and Housing Development: What We Know,”
Cityscape, 8, 5–19. 2
Silver, M. and S. Heravi (2007): “The difference between hedonic imputation indexes
and time dummy hedonic indexes,” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 25,
239–246. 8
Stacy, C., C. Davis, Y. S. Freemark, L. Lo, G. MacDonald, V. Zheng, and
R. Pendall (2023): “Land-use reforms and housing costs: Does allowing for increased
density lead to greater affordability?” Urban Studies, 1–22. 3
Wetzstein, S. (2017): “The global urban housing affordability crisis,” Urban Studies, 54,
3159–3177. 2
29