Procedia Economics and Finance 35 ( 2016 ) 349 – 358
Available online at www.sciencedirect.com
2212-5671 © 2016 The Authors. Published by Elsevier B.V. This is an open access article under the CC BY-NC-ND license
(http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/).
Peer-reviewed under responsibility of Universiti Tenaga Nasional
doi: 10.1016/S2212-5671(16)00043-5
ScienceDirect
7th International Economics & Business Management Conference, 5th & 6th October 2015
An Evolution of Mudarabah Contract: A Viewpoint From Classical
and Contemporary Islamic Scholars
Noraina Mazuin Sapuan
a,*
a
Department of Finance and Economics, Universiti Tenaga Malaysia, 26700 Muadzam Shah, Pahang, Malaysia
Abstract
Currently, in the competitive Islamic financial system, mudarabah (profit sharing) is seen as an alternative mechanism in
financing techniques that differentiate it from the conventional financing that consist interest mechanism. Sin
ce its introduction,
mudarabah (profit sharing) has gone through various evolution to fulfill the needs of the fast-developing Islamic financial
mark
et. However, in the current Islamic financial system, mudarabah (profit sharing) has become less preferable compared to
Islamic debt financing instruments such as m
urabahah and bai’ bithaman ajil. This is caused by the existence of asymmetric
information that continuously presents in mudarabah (profit sharing) contracts and creates problems of adverse selection and
moral hazard. Due to this, mudarabah (profit sharing) has declined it importance as a financing vehicle. Therefore, the objectives
o
f this study are twofolds, first, to examine the thought and evolution of mudarabah (profit sharing) from the viewpoints of
classical an
d contemporary Islamic scholars and second, to evaluate the asymmetric information that continuously exist in this
ty
pe of contract.
© 2015 The Authors. Published by Elsevier B.V.
Peer-reviewed under responsibility of Universiti Tenaga Nasional.
Keywords: Mudarabah (profit sharing) contract; evolution; classical; contemporary Islamic scholars
1. Introduction
*Corresponding author. Tel:+60-9-455-2020; fax: +60-9-455-2006
Email: Noraina@uniten.edu.my
© 2016 The Authors. Published by Elsevier B.V. This is an open access article under the CC BY-NC-ND license
(http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/).
Peer
-reviewed under responsibility of Universiti Tenaga Nasional
brought to you by COREView metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk
provided by Elsevier - Publisher Connector
350 Noraina Mazuin Sapuan / Procedia Economics and Finance 35 ( 2016 ) 349 – 358
Equity financing instruments for Islamic business contracts are based on the mudarabah (profit sharing) and
musharakah (profit loss sharing) prin
ciples. These financing methods are an alternative to conventional debt
financing that is based on rate of interest (riba). Equity financing involves mutual sharing of risks and profits,
depending on the performance of the investment project. In the case of mudarabah (profit sharing), the contracting
parties i.e. the fund provider (rabbulmal)-who supplies the financial capital and the entrepreneur (mu
darib)-who
supplies the expertise and management, will collectively take part in profit sharing venture. Profits derived from the
pro
ject will be shared according to the predetermined profit-sharing ratio such as 60:40 or 70:30 by both parties. In
th
e event of failure, all losses must be borne by the fund provider (rabbulmal), while the entrepreneur (mu
darib)
would have lost his time and effort.
However, from the practical side, mud
arabah (profit sharing) contract is less preferred compare to debt
financing instruments because of the asymmetric information problems that continuously exist in this mode of
financing. The asymmetric information on mudarabah (profit sharing) contract, especially on the asset side,
n
ormally occurred as an entrepreneur (mudarib) who manage the mudarabah (profit sharing) fund have full control
of
the project and have more information regarding the project and its prof
itability which the Islamic bank (rabbul
mall) does not usually have access to. The inefficiency in information delegation will generate two major problems,
i.e. adverse selection and moral hazard that makes it difficult f
or the contracting parties to achieve an optimal
contract. Due to this, there is a lack of
interest among Islamic financial institutions to use mudarabah (profit sharing)
as a financing vehicle. According to Bacha (1997), mud
arabah (profit sharing) has lower expected returns and
higher risks; this inequality in the distribution of risk and return has caused full-fledged and window Islamic banks
to red
uce the utilization of mudarabah (profit sharing) financing in their investment.
Therefore, the objectives of this study are twofolds: first, to exa
mine the thought and evolution of mudarabah
(profit sharing) contract from the viewpoints of classical a
nd contemporary Islamic scholars, and second, to evaluate
the inherent problems i.e. assymetric information that prevail in this type of contract.
The remainder of this paper proceeds as follows: Section 2 briefly reviews the mudarabah (profit sharing) from
th
e classical islamic scholars viewpoint. Section 3 discusses the evolution of m
udarabah contract from
contemporary islamic scholar viewpoints. Section 4 highlights the asymmetric information problem in mudar
abah
(profit sharing) contract. Finally, section 5 concluded the study.
2. Mudarabah (profit sharing) Fro
m The Classical Islamic Scholars Viewpoint
Mudarabah (
profit sharing) is one of the earliest business forms used by the pre-Arabs for trade activities.
Different terms are used to mean mudarab
ah (profit sharing): muqaradah is commonly used by the Hanafi and
Hambali scholars and qirad is used by the Maliki and Shafie scholars.
Even though mudar
abah (profit sharing) has no basis in the Quran or the Sunnah, it was employed by the early
Muslims to conduct trade. The term “mudarabah (profit sharing)” is derived from al-darb al-ard which means
traveling through the land” as mentioned in the following verse of the al-Quran:
“….others traveling the land seeking of Allah’s bounty” (Al-Muzzammil: 20).
It was also approved by Prophet Muhammad (S.A.W) as reported by Suhayb r.a.:
“Three m
atters that have the blessing (of Allah (S.W.T)) i.e. a deferred sale, muqaradah (mudarabah (profit
sharing)), mixing the wheat and barley for domestic use and not for sale” (Sunan Ibn Majan)
Mudarabah (profit sharing
) is also known as “silent partnership” (Al-Zuhayli, 2007) whereby it involves a
financier (rabbulmal), who provides a specific amount of capital and acts as a sleeping or dormant partner and an
entrepreneur (mudarib), who acts as a trustee or a business agent. The mudarib is required to utilize and manage the
capital in
prudence and good manner to generate optimal profits for the mudarabah (profit sharing) investment,
w
hile adhering to the laws of Shariah. The mudarib does not invest any property in the business venture except for
h
is knowledge and skills. He is also not entitled to claim any wage for conducting the business venture. Mudarabah
(profit sharing) is one of the oldest
business forms used by the pre-Arabs for trade activities. Literally, the word
mudarabah (profit sharing) is derived from the phrase “al-darbfi al-ard
which means to make a journey (ISRA,
2011). The literal meaning of this partnership is that, in the past this contract required the parties involved to make a
journey to run their business.
351
Noraina Mazuin Sapuan / Procedia Economics and Finance 35 ( 2016 ) 349 – 358
Generally, mudarabah (profit sharing) is a partnership in profit whereby one party provides capital (rabbul
maal) and the other party (mudarib) provides labour. The profit, if any, will be shared between them at a mutually
agreed ratio, In case of a loss, it will be borne by the fund provider (r
abbul maal) and the mudarib will lose his
efforts.
Different terms have been used for mudar
abah (profit sharing) such as muqaradah that was commonly used by
the Hanafi and Hambali scholars and qirad was used by the Maliki and Shafie scholars. Mudar
abah (profit sharing)
is also known as “silent partnership” (Al-Zuhayli, 2007) whereby it involves a financier/fund provider (rabbul
ma
al), who provides a specific amount of capital and acts as a sleeping or dormant partner and an entrepreneur
(mudarib), w
ho acts as a trustee or a business agent.
2.1 Legitimacy of Mudarabah (
profit sharing) Contract
The legitimacy of mudar
abah (profit sharing) contract has been established in the Quran, Hadis and the
consensus of Muslim scholars (Ijma’). The pesimissibility of mudarabah (profit sharing) contract has been
m
entioned in the following verse of the al-Quran:
“….others traveling the land seeking of Allah’s bounty” (Surah Al-Muzzammil: 20)
There two hadiths which stated this partnership arrangement and approved by the Prophet Muhammad (S.A.W):
“Ibnu Abbas (may Allah be pleased with him
) reported that: “When Abbas Ibn Abd al-Muttalib gave his property
to someone for mudarabah (profit sharing), he stipulated conditions for his partner not to bring the capital onto the
sea; and not to bring with him the capital crossing a valley; and not to buy livestock with the capital; and if his
partner violates the conditions, he should guarantee the loss occurred. These conditions have been bought to the
attention of Prophet Muhammad (peace be upon him) and he approved them”.
(Narrated by Al-Bayhaqi in Al Sunan al-Kubra, as cited in Abdul Rahman, 2012)
2.2 Pillars and Conditions of Mudarabah (profit sharing)
2.2.1 Sighah (Ijab and Qabul)
Basically, the condition related to the sig
hah of mudarabah (profit sharing) is similar to those other contracts
which constitute an offer and acceptance. Mudarabah (profit sharing) is concluded when the parties use words that
clearly indicate the contract of mudar
abah (profit sharing) in their offer and acceptance.
2.2.2 The Contracting Parties
The contracting parties consist of fund provider (r
abbul maal) and entrepreneur (mudarib) that have a sound
mind and able to take responsibilities. Fund provider (r
abbul maal) will provide capital to the entrepreneur
(mudarib) for investing it in a business enterprise b
y applying his skills and efforts.
2.2.3 Subject Matter and Conditions of Mudarabah (profit sharing)
(i) Types of Capital
There are various opinions on the types of capital for muda
rabah (profit sharing) contract. Mudarabah (profit
sharing) capital is the wealth entrusted to the mudarib for productive use and at the same time to promote mutual
g
oodwill between the contracting parties. According to Ibn Rushd, one of Maliki scholar, the majority of the jurists
agree that the investment capital should be in the form of monetary assets or currency (dinar or dirham) as it
possesses intrinsic value as a medium of exchange and legal tender that is accepted by all parties involved in the
contract (Borhan & Sa’ari, 2007).
Meanwhile, most Islamic scholars rule out the use of non-monetary assets or in kind as capital, as it generates
unc
ertainty (gharar) on the estimation of the initial value of the assets, which may be different according to the
person
s evaluating the said property. Furthermore, the fluctuation of prices of non-monetary investments may lead
to in
equitable advantages and disadvantages between the contracting parties. For example, if the prices of
commodities increase when the contract is executed, the entrepreneur will benefit from the price rise as his share of
352 Noraina Mazuin Sapuan / Procedia Economics and Finance 35 ( 2016 ) 349 – 358
profits will increase upon termination of the contract. Meanwhile, if the price declines, the market value of the
commodities drops and investors have to face losses and less profit distribution (Borhan and Sa’ari, 2007).
Ho
wever, two legal scholars, Ibn Abi Layla and Al-Awzai both dissents on the issue, perm
itting the use of non-
monetary assets as capital (Al-Zuhayli, 2007).
On the other hand, Abu Hanifa, Malik and Ibn Hanbali permit listing the price of non-monetary assets as
mudar
abah (profit sharing) capital. The mudarib can sell the assets provided by
the fund provider (rabbulmal) and
use the price as capital for the contract. However, al-Shafie disagrees with this idea due to the inexistence of
phy
sical assets upon the contract (al-Zuhayli, 2007).
Most Islamic scholars also agreed that the capital should not be in the form of debt owned by the potential
entrep
reneur from the fund provider (rabbulmal) (Al-Zuhayli, 2007). The rationale of this ruling is to prevent
mudar
abah (profit sharing) from becoming a mode for the r
abbul maal to recover his debt and as a result gain
benefit from the charge or interest. However, if the debt has been paid to the rabbul maal and then the money
deliv
ered again to the entrepreneur upon his need, the silent partnership remains valid. If the creditor instructs the
debtor to use the money that he owes him as capital, the contract is rendered defective. Abu Hanifa, the Malikis, the
Shafies and the Hanbalis agree that if the debtor continues to use the money he is owed, all profit and losses from
the investment would be his and the debt remains intact (Al-Zuhayli, 2007).
In order to collect debt from debtors, all scholars agree that th
e capital provider or creditor may hire an agent to
do the task on his behalf and then use the money as capital in the silent partnership. In the case of deposit money,
the Hanafis, Shafies and Hambalis, if someone is entrusted with a deposit and the depositors ask him to use the
m
oney as capital in silent partnership between them, the contract is valid. However, the Maliki scholars believe that
pawned and deposited money is too similar to debts and thus do not qualify as capital.
Meanwhile, in terms of capital protection, all classical s
cholars collectively agree on the prohibition of a
guarantee scheme for mudarabah (profit sharing) because it is not relevant to mudarabah (profit sharing) ventures.
Since mudar
abah (profit sharing) operates under a profit-loss-sharing scheme and not a loan, therefore collateral and
guarantees are not required. According to Rosly (2005) the idea of giving guarantees on mudarabah (profit sharing)
contracts diverges from the basic philosophy of profit, loss sharing, i.e. al-ghorm bil ghonm (no reward without
ris
k).
(ii) Distribution of Profits and Losses
The entrepreneur (mu
darib) is required to utilize and manage the capital in prudence and good manner to
generate optimal profits for the mudarabah (profit sharing) investment, while adhering to the laws of Shar
iah. The
entrepreneur (mudarib) does not invest any property in the business venture except for his knowledge and skills. He
is also not entitled to claim any wage for conducting the business venture.
The fund provider (
rabbulmal) and entrepreneur (mudarib) are eligible to attain shares of profits in return for
the investment capital of the former and the latter, for his effort to materialize the profit through business ventures.
All Islamic scholars agree that the ratio in which the profits are to be distributed needs to be determined ex-ante to
avoid an
y disagreement after the business has been conducted. The ownership of the capital or invested assets
remain with the fund provider (rabbulmal) at all times. The fund provider (
rabbulmal) is liable in the event of losses
incurred by market risks, while the entrepreneur (mudarib) will lose his time and effort. T
he liability of the fund
provider (rabbulmal) in mud
arabah (profit sharing) is limited to the extent of his contribution to the capital and no
more. However, if the loss is due to negligence or moral hazard (ghasib), the loss will be absorbed by the
entrepreneur (mudarib).
(iii) The Role of Contracting Parties in Mudarabah (profit sharing) Contract
Mudarabah (p
rofit sharing) contracts can be divided into two types, namely unrestricted (al-mudarabah al-
mutalaqah) and restricted (al-mudarabah al-muqayyadah).
In the unrestricted case, the agreement does not specify
the time period, the location of the business and the specific type of trade or service to be carried out. Meanwhile,
under restricted mudarabah (profit sharing), the entrepreneur (mu
darib) is confined to certain conditions set forth by
the fund provider (rabbulmal). If the entrepreneur (mudarib) fails to comply with the restrictions of the fund
prov
ider (rabbulmal), he will be fully responsible for any resulting losses.
353
Noraina Mazuin Sapuan / Procedia Economics and Finance 35 ( 2016 ) 349 – 358
The Maliki and Shafie scholars approve that mudarabah (profit sharing) contract should be unrestricted as it
encourages the entrepreneur to find more opportunities for better profit-earning. However, Abu Hanifa and Ahmad
Ibn
Hambali agree on restricting certain aspects of the mudarabah (profit sharing) contract, e.g. the time period and
choice of the right agent in order to reduce business risks (Al-Zuhayli, 2007).
(iv) The Dissolution and Termination of Mu
darabah (profit sharing) Contract
The mudar
abah (profit sharing) contract is designed to fulfil the needs of the fund provider (rabbulmal) and the
entrepreneur (mudarib) and to protect their interests. The contract is n
ormally dissolved when both parties have
agreed on the completion of the business venture with the settlement of profit distribution and closing of accounts.
All the Islamic sc
holars agree that mudarabah (profit sharing) is non-binding before commencement of the
work and may be dissolved by either party. According to al-Zuhayli (2007), the Hanafi, Hambali and Shafie scholars
agree th
at either party can dissolve the contract at any time and that the contract is automatically terminated with the
death of either party. But the Maliki scholars disagree with the other scholars and assert that once work begins, the
contract becomes binding on both parties. In the case where one of the parties dies, the contract can be inherited by
his heirs. According to non-Shafie scholars, the contract is also terminated if one of the parties becomes mentally
un
stable; however, the Hanafis rule that the mudar
abah (profit sharing) contract will not be void if the rabbul maal
is put under legal guardianship.
In terms of capital requirement, the Hanafi scholars rul
e that the contract can be dissolved only if the
partnership capital is in monetary form. But the Shafie and Hambali scholars agree that the dissolution of the
partnership is valid even though the capital is non-monetary, as long as both parties agree to sell it and share the
prof
it according to the pre-determined ratio.
3. Contemporary Islamic Scholar Viewpoints
3.1 The Dynamic Evolution of Mudarabah (Profit Sharing) Contract
The development of new products in the modern Islamic financial system is based on the rulings of
co
ntemporary scholars that the contract is valid as long as it does not contradict the provisions in the al-Quran and
Sun
nah. This belief is consistent with the opinion of Ibn Taymiyya (peace be upon him).
“The underlying principle in contracts and stipulations is
permissible (ibaha) and valid. Any (contracts and
stipulations) is prohibited and void only if there is an explicit test (from al-Quran, the Sunnah and consensus) or a
qiyas
, proving its prohibition and voiding.”
(Narrated by Ibn Taymiyya in al-Fatawa,
as cited in Abdul Rahman, 2012)
Generally, many contemporary Islamic economic scholars enco
urage the usage of profit loss sharing (PLS) i.e.
mudarabah (profit sharing) and m
usyarakah (profit loss sharing) instruments due to its absence of riba and gharar
for the development of current econ
omic activities. However, in reality the PLS contract is less favoured by
financial institutions because of various barriers such as legal requirements and moral hazard problems.
3.1.2 Two-Tier Mudarabah
Generally, the mudar
abah (profit sharing) contract consists of one rabbul maal and one mudarib. However,
according to Maliki scholars there is no restriction on the number of investors (rabbul maals) or entrepreneurs
(mudaribs) in
the same contract with the permission of the capital provider.
According to the Hanafi scholar al-Sarakhsi, in the case of several entrepreneurs (mu
daribs), the mudaribs can
only act in accordance with mutual agreement and approval of the investor. If one of the entrepreneur (mudarib) act
independently without his colleagues’ or investors’ permission, he becomes liable to the investor for any losses due
to the independent and the unauthorised action (Borhan, 2004).
However, the Shafie jurists have different views on multi-tier mudar
abah (profit sharing). Most Shafie scholars
prohibit the use of mudarabah (profit sharing) contract with several entrepreneur (mudarib) regardless of any
permission given by the capital provider. Such contract is regarded as void if it is implemented. Yet, a few Shafie
j
urists such as al-Shirazi allow the implementation of this contract (Borhan and Sa’ari, 2007).
354 Noraina Mazuin Sapuan / Procedia Economics and Finance 35 ( 2016 ) 349 – 358
Many new contracts have emerged in the contemporary period. Basically, modern PLS instruments are formed
based on studies by the classical Islamic scholars; however, new developments are introduced to fulfil the
requirements and demands of modern industries. According to Al-Zuhayli (2007), among the contracts currently
availab
le that use the mudarabah (profit sharing) concept are; simple partnership (s
harikat al-tawsiyah al-basitah),
particular partnership (sharikat muhassah), joint stock companies (sharikat musahamah) and hybrid limited
partnership (sharikat al-tawsiyah bi-l-ashum).
Figure 1: Financing Process under Mudarabah (profit sharing) Contract
Contemporary scholars agree that capital can be in the form of monetary or non-monetary assets. Nevertheless,
debts or loans cannot be accepted as capital. Mudarabah (profit sharing) contracts can be either single-tier or multi-
tiered. In a single-tier contract, the fund provider (
rabbulmal) deals directly with the entrepreneur (mudarib),
meanwhile in two-tier contracts (Refer to Figure 1), fund provider (
rabbulmal) entrust their funds to an agent, who
acts as an intermediary and who later deals with the entrepreneurs chosen to execu
te the projects. The entrepreneur
(mudarib) o
f a mudarabah (profit sharing) contract may assign the capital to another entrepreneur (mudarib) in
another mudarabah (profit sharing) contract with the permission of the primary capital provider. The profit gain
from the investment will be shared between the fund provider (rabbulmal) and the first entrepreneur (mu
darib)
based on the pre-determined ratio between them and the balance w
ill then be shared with the other mudaribs.
However, in the case of losses, it will be borne solely by the rabbul maal except if the loss was due to the
n
egligence of the mudarib. The application of unrestrictive mudarabah (profit sharing) i.e. al-mudarabah al-
mutalaqah is considered the most suitable contract to be impleme
nted in the modern investment structure whereby it
would allow the entrepreneur (mudarib) more innovation and creativity in executing the business venture.
3.1.2 Capital Guaranteed
Contemporary scholars also approve on the idea
of giving a third party guarantee (al-kafala) to the mudarabah
(profit sharing) capital as it would be able to mitigate risk exposures and secure the return of the capital. The
guarantee can protect investors (rabbul maal) from misconduct or fraud, but not from market risk. According to
Dalla Albaraka, giving a guarantee to the entrepreneur (mu
darib) in mudarabah (profit sharing) capital is prohibited.
Yet, if the guarantee is given by the government, then it is allowed (Rosly, 2005). Currently, third party guarantees
can
be obtained from the government or from private entities.
In June 2002, the Shariah Advisory Committee of Bank Neg
ara Malaysia ruled that third party guarantee is
permissible for Islamic deposits. This guarantee scheme is based on the concept of mutual guarantee (al-kafala)
a
mong Islamic financial institutions as participants of the scheme. This scheme does not violate the Shariah
355
Noraina Mazuin Sapuan / Procedia Economics and Finance 35 ( 2016 ) 349 – 358
principles since its objective is to protect the public interest (maslahah), especially the depositors and the banking
industry. However, Islamic banking institutions need to ensure that the funds gained from Islamic deposit insurance
schemes are invested in Shariah-compliant instruments. In line with this, the government of Malaysia has introduced
P
erbadanan Insurans Deposit Malaysia (PIDM) or the Malaysia Deposit Insurance Corporation (MDIC), a fully
guaranteed government agency as a third party to offer insurance coverage on deposits based on Shariah principles.
Furthermore, in 2005, Bank Negara Malaysia (BNM) app
roved Credit Guarantee Corporation Berhad (CGC) as
a third party-guarantor for business ventures with the implemen
tation of Islamic Direct Access Guarantee Scheme
(DAGS-i). In this scheme, the guarantor will charge fees f
or the guarantee services given exclusively to Islamic
financing products offered by Islamic financial institutions to their customers (BNM, 2008).
3.1.3 Establishment of Pr
ofit Equalization Reserve
In year 2004, the Malaysian Islamic banks have introduced a new mechanism in distributing profits for the
mudar
abah (profit sharing) investments. The new mechanism is known as Profit Equalisation Reserve (PER). The
profit equalisation reserve is the amount appropriated by the Islamic bank (rabbul maal) out of the their gross profit
such as from mudarabah (profit sharing) profit, before allocating it as an entrepreneur (mudarib) share, in order to
maintain a certain level of return on investment for the Investment Account Holders (IAH) and to increase owners’
equity (ISRA, 2011).
According to Shaharuddin (2010), in the real banking busin
ess, the monthly rate of return recorded by the
Islamic bank (rabbul maal) throughout a year is inconsistent due to the flux of bad debt profit, provisioning and total
deposit. Thus, in order to mitigate the fluctuation of the rate of return, the Central Bank of Malaysia has demanded
all the Islamic bank (r
abbul maal) in this country to implement the PER mechanism.
This provision/reserve will be u
sed whenever Islamic bank (rabbul maal) record a low profit. As such PER is
viewed as a reserve that is built up in good times to cater for the need in a bad times (Ismail and Shahimi, 2006).
T
his reserve is created with the purpose of covering the potential losses or as a face of fluctuations in return for the
transaction conducted (Che Arshad and Ismail, 2011). It is also to ensure that Islamic banks have a fixed and
competitive returns to the Investment Account Holders (IAH). Therefore, indirectly profit equalisation reserve
similarly performs as a guaranteed (daman) on mudarabah (profit sharing) capital taken from the mu
darib’s profit.
Although the purpose of PER is undeniably important, its i
mplementation, however causes more confusion. The
Islamic banks may argue that they obtain the depositor’s permission based on the standard form signed at the
beginning of the contract. But, the level of transparency pertaining to this matter is very low. The acceptance of the
PER method in the Malaysian Islamic banking practices indicates the flexible approach adopted by their
Su
pervisory Shariah Board members in modifying the Islamic commercial contracts (Shaharuddin, 2010).
4. Asymmetric Information Problem in Mudarabah (Profit Sharing) Contract
Generally, Islamic financial institutions prefer to u
se debt financing instruments such as murabahah (short term
debt) or bai’ bithaman ajil (long term debt) in their business activities as compared
to equity financing tools.
Adverse selection and moral hazard problems are the reasons why equity financing, especially mudarabah (profit
s
haring) is a less popular choice as a financing method in Islamic financial institutions.
In reality, investments using mudar
abah (profit sharing) are very risky as the entrepreneur (mudarib), often has
more information about the proposed project and its profitability which the Islamic bank does not usually have
access to. Hence, it leads to imperfect information between the contracting parties (Siddiqui, 2008). Meanwhile,
Ismail and Tohirin (2008) and Khalil, Rickwood and Murinde (2002) discovered mudarabah venture can become
unproductive when Islamic banks fail to embark effective screening process in
the selection of suitable entrepreneur
to manage a business venture before contracting and at the same time failed to monitor the entrepreneur’s actions
af
ter the contract is implemented. This generally related to the ability of entrepreneur to conceal information
regarding his background and capabilities before contracting and his disguise actions after the contract is
implemented.
Sarker (2000) also revealed that the asymmetric information in mudar
abah contract also cause by the untruthful
behaviour of entrepreneur that failed to report the outcome accurately. Meanwhile, Iqbal and Lewis (2009)
disco
vered that entrepreneurs with below average profit favour equity contract after debt contract in order to
minimize losses in case of failure. In contrast, managers with above average earning prefer to use debt financing in
356 Noraina Mazuin Sapuan / Procedia Economics and Finance 35 ( 2016 ) 349 – 358
order to maximize their gains in case of success. This is in line with the finding from Allen and Gale (1992) where
better quality firms use debt financing as a signal of their superior quality. The problem becomes more serious as the
existence of restriction of using collateral for these assets by the regulator. Investment using mudarabah contract is
also very risky as there is no certainty on returns.
Adverse selection is the true risk of the entrepreneur (mu
darib) before the investment is executed. Meanwhile,
the problem of moral hazard arises when the mudarib is not motivated to fulfil the interests of the project other than
f
or his benefit. It is also related to the risk that the entrepreneur would conceal information concerning his abilities
and background before the contract and that he would perform independently after the contract is executed (Ismail
and Tohirin, 2008). Furthermore, according to Dar and Presley (2000), such problems can also exist when the
entrepreneur dishonestly under-reports or reduces the declared profits.
4.1 Remedial Action to Reduce Asymmetric Information in Mudarabah (Profit Sharing) Contract
Since the Islamic financial system runs on the principle of risk-sharing, disclosure of information between
parties is v
ery critical. Information regarding the possible combination on how the capital is used, the objective of
the rabbulmal and performance of the venture, among others, must be transparent. A
ccording to Siddiqui (2008),
risk and equity sharing contracts are related to various investment risks such as credit, market and operating risks
which are the results of information imbalance, leading to a problem of adverse selection and moral hazard. Ismail
an
d Tohirin (2008) reveal that the reason behind unsuccessful mudarabah (profit sharing) business ventures in
Islamic banking is lack of expertise in monitoring the entrepreneur’s operations. Investments using mudarabah
(profit sharing) contract are also very ris
ky as there is no certainty on returns.
4.1.1 Incentive Compatible Contract
Presley and Sessions (1994) and Ahmed (2002) recommended the implementation of incentive-compatible
co
ntracts to allow more efficient disclosure of information between
the contracting parties. The agency theory states
that the agent may not always act in the best interests of the financier. Therefore, the investor needs to set
appropriate incentives for the agent to earn higher return for the project.
4.1.2 Screening and Monitoring Process
Abalkhail and Presley (2002) emphasized on the use of screening process to overcome the problem of
in
complete contract that create an adverse selection and moral hazard problems. Sarker (2000) and Ismail and
Ahm
ad (2006) suggested the usage of screening as well as monitoring process to supervise the actions of the
en
trepreneur in the financing and investment activities. According to Jensen and Meckling (1976), monitoring
expenditure is an agency cost that is directly related to the financier’s monitoring of the agent’s behavior. Effective
monitoring will reduces the a
gency costs even if the agent’s information and actions cannot be fully monitored.
Various benefits can be shared by both principal (capital provider) and agent (entrep
reneur) when the agency costs
been minimize. Ahmed (2002) stated that asymmetric inform
ation can be resolved if the rabbul maal can gather
more information on the operations of the firm especially through the monitoring process. Rabbul maal should
evaluate and monitor the mudarib’s visions, objectives, market strategy, financial strategy and production process
w
hen the contract being executed. Recent studies by Muda and Ismail (2010) and Wan Kamaruddin and Ismail
(2013) had proved that Mudharabah contract can achieve optimality and mitigate asymmetric problem as well as
minimise transaction cost.
4.1.3 Muslims’ Behavior
From the Islamic perspective, risk and uncertainty can be mitigated through good behavior, as recommended by
Isla
mic teachings. The al-Quran instructs trustworthiness (amanah) (A
l.Baraqah, 282) and insists on fairness and
justice in economic activities. Allah (S.W.T) commands such behaviour to generate harmony among mankind to
ach
ieve Maqasid as Shariah. As mentioned by Metwally (1997), the objective of an Islamic firm is not profit
357
Noraina Mazuin Sapuan / Procedia Economics and Finance 35 ( 2016 ) 349 – 358
maximization; nevertheless, Islamic firms aim to achieve reasonable (fair) profit since Islam instructs Muslims to be
moderate in pursuit of profit and wealth.
4.1.4 Corporate Governance in the Management of Contract
Basically, corporate governance is related to the internal in
tegrity of a corporation that promotes a corporate
fairness, transparency and accountability in the management. Meanwhile, Islamic corporate governance is
establis
hed from the epistemological aspect of Tawhid, embedded the Shari’ah rules and emphasize on the principle
of consultation (shura) bet
ween every stakeholder that involved in the investment activities.
Currently, many Islamic scholars try to emphasize on the role of
Islamic corporate governance to mitigate
agency problems in Islamic financing instruments especially in mudarabah (profit sharing) contract. The special
criterion that is highlighted in Islamic corporate governance is the role of sharia (the latter will be known as s
huratic
process in the decision making process.
In the contemporary practice, s
hura have been suggested as one of the monitoring mechanism to attain
accountability, fairness and transparency in the governance of Islamic corporations (Abdul Rahman, 1998; Iqbal and
Mirakhor, 2004; and Hasan, 2009).
The member of s
hura will comprises of Islamic banks, shareholders, employees and the managers of firms.
Through shura, every party involved will participate in the discussion and will open the door for information to be
disclo
sed and delivered efficiently from the manager to the stakeholders, thus this will narrow down the asymmetric
information in the venture. This is consistent with the spirit of Islam that emphasis on the importance of
trustworthiness and cooperative among Muslim. At the same time, it is to ensure that every activity and decision on
the business venture, especially that based on mudarabah (profit sharing) contract are mutually agreed by all parties
in
volved before the realization of the contract as the capital provider cannot participate in the management activities.
5. Conclusion
Mudarabah (pr
ofit sharing) has through various evolutionary changes and modernizations since its practice in
the pre-Islamic era. The improvement on existing mudarabah (profit sharing) conditions in modern mudar
abah
(profit sharing) is acceptable prov
ided that it does not contradict with the provisions in the al-Quran and Sunnah.
The intention of this development is to fulfil the needs of the modern communities and the fast-growing Islamic
f
inancial market. However, in reality, mudarabah (profit sharing) is less preferab
le compared to Islamic debt
financing instruments. This is due to the existence of imperfect information that is inherent in mudarabah (profit
sh
aring) contracts and creates problem of adverse selection and moral hazard, also kn
own as agency problems. As a
result, mudarabah (profit sharing) has declined in importance as a financing vehicle.
In order to overcome the agency problem, screen
ing, monitoring and supervision of the mudarib (entrepreneur)
by the capital provider have been suggested as the best tool
to mitigate this problem. Meanwhile, from the Islamic
perspective, the principle of a
manah (trusteeship), fairness and shura (mutual consultation) have also been pointed
out as part of reliable solutions to reduce the agency problem in mudarabah (p
rofit sharing) contracts. As a faithful
Muslim, the entrepreneur needs to work in a trustworthy manner and carry out his responsibility truthfully with the
intention of obtaining Allah’s blessings and not for his self-interest.
References
Ahmed, H., 2002. Incentive-compatible profit-sharing contracts: a theoretical treatment, Islamic Banking and Finance: New Perspective on
Profit-Sharing and Risk, Edward Elgar Publishing Limited, 40-54.
Abalkhail, M., Presley J.R., 2002. How informal risk capital investors manage asymmetric information in profit/loss-sharing contracts, Islamic
Ba
nking and Finance: New Perspective on Profit-Sharing and Risk, Edward Elgar Publishing Limited, 111-134.
Abdul Rahman, A. R., 1998. Issues in Corporate Accountability and Governance: An Islamic Perspective. American Journal of Islamic Social
Sc
iences 15 (1), 55-70.
Abdul Rahman, Z., 2012. Contract and The Product of Islamic Banking (2
nd
Edition), Kuala Lumpur, Malaysia: CERT Publication Sdn. Bhd.
Allen, F., Gale, D., 1992. Measurement Distortion and Missing Contingencies in Optimal Contracts. Economic Theory 2 (1), 1-26.
Al-Zuhayli, W., 2007. Financial Transaction in Islamic Jurisprudence, Vol. 2, Dar al Fikr in Damascus.
Bacha, O. I., 1997. Adapting Mudarabah (profit sharing) Financing to Contemporary Realities: A Proposed Financing Structure, Munich Personal
R
ePEc Archieve, http://ub.uni-muenchen.de/12732/
358 Noraina Mazuin Sapuan / Procedia Economics and Finance 35 ( 2016 ) 349 – 358
Bank Negara Malaysia, 2008. Syariah Resolution, Bank Negara, Kafalah in Mudarabah (profit sharing) Contract:
http://www.bnm.gov.my/microsites/financial/pdf/resolutions/08_kafalah.pdf
Bank Negara Malaysia, 2009. Draft of Shariah Parameter Reference 3 (SPR3): Mudarabah (profit sharing) Contract.
w
ww.bnm.gov.my/documents/.../attachment_mudarabah (profit sharing)_contract.pdf
Borhan, J. T., 2004. The Agent-Manager s Conduct of Mudarabah (profit sharing) Contract in Islamic Commercial Law, Journal of Syariah 12
(1
), 1-20.
Borhan, J. T., Sa’ari, C. Z., 2007. Sumbangan Pemikiran Ibn Rushd (M. 595/1198) Dalam Muamalah: Analisis Terhadap Akad Al-Mudarabah
(p
rofit sharing) Dalam Bidayah al-Mujtahid WanihayahAl-Muqtasid, Jurnal Usuluddin, 26, 133-147.
Che Arshad, N., Ismail, A.G., 2011. Regulation on the Paramaterized of Mudharabah Contract: A Critical Analysis. International Journal of
E
conomic Research 2(3), 157-189.
Dar, H.A., Presley, J.R., 2000. Lack of Profit Loss Sharing in Islamic Banking, International Journal of Islamic Financial Service
s 2(2).
Hasan, Z., 2009. Corporate Governance: Western and Islamic Perspectives. International Review of Business Research Papers 5 (1), 277-293.
Iqbal, Z., Lewis., 2009. An Islamic Perspective on Governance. USA, Massachusetts: Edward Elgar Publishing Inc.
Iqbal, Z., Mirakhor, A., 2004. Stakeholders Model of Governance in Islamic Economic System. Islamic Economic Studies 11(2), 43-63.
Ismail A.G., Ahmad., 2006. Does the Islamic finance system design matter?,Humanomics 22(1), 5-46.
Ismail, A.G., Shahimi, S., 2006. An Empirical Analysis of Profit Equalization Reserve Decisions. Working Papers in Islamic Econom
ics and
Finance No. WIEF0604, UKM
Ismail, A.G., Tohirin, A., 2008. Finance and Growth: Does the Modes Play a Role? Accounting and Finance Conference (iBAF 2008), U
niversiti
Sains Islam Malaysia.
ISRA, 2011. Islamic Financial System: Principles & Operations (1
st
Edition). Kuala Lumpur: International Shari’ah Research Academy for
Islamic Finance.
Jensen M.C., Meckling, W.H., 1976. Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behviour, Agency Costs and Ownership structure, Journal of Financial
E
conomics 13, 5-50.
Khalil, A. F., Rickwood, C., Murinde, V., 2002. Evidence on Agency Contractual Problems in Mudarabah Financing Operations by Islamic
Ba
nks, in Islamic Banking and Finance: New Perspective on Profit-Sharing and Risk, edited by Iqbal, M. and Llewellyn, D.. UK: Edward
E
lgar Publishing Limited.
Metwally, M. M., 1997. Economic Consequences of Applying Islamic Principles in Muslim Society, International Journal of Social Economics
24(
7/8/9), 941-957.
Muda, R., Ismail, A.G., 2010. Profit-Loss Sharing and Value Creation in Islamic Banks. Journal of Business and Policy Research 5(2), 262-281.
Presley, J.R., Sessions, J.G., 1994. Islamic Economics: The Emergence of a New Paradigm. The Economic Journal, 584-596.
Rosly, S., 2005. Critical Issues on Islamic Banking and Financial Markets: Islamic Economics, Banking & Finance, Investment, Takaful and
F
inancial Planning. Dinamas Publication, 2005.
Sarker, A., 2000. Islamic Business Contracts, Agency Problem and Theory of the Islamic Firm, International Journal of Islamic Fin
ancial
Services 1(2).
Shaharuddin, A., 2010. Maslahah-Mafsadah Approach in Assessing the Shari’ah Compliance of Islamic Banking Products, International Journal
o
f Business and Social Science 1(1),129 -136.
Siddiqui, A., 2008. Financial Contracts, Risk and Performance of Islamic Banking. Managerial Finance 34(10), 680-694.
Vogel, F. and Hayes, S. L., 1998. Islamic Law and Finance: Religion, Risk and Return. Kluwer Law International, Netherland.
Wan Kamaruddin, W. N., Ismail, A.G., 2013. Profit Sharing
and Loss Bearing in Financial Intermediation Theory. Investment Management and
Financial Innovations 10(2), 184-192.